Podchaser Logo
Home
US Indebtedness & Capitalism’s Internal Contradictions

US Indebtedness & Capitalism’s Internal Contradictions

Released Monday, 8th May 2023
Good episode? Give it some love!
US Indebtedness & Capitalism’s Internal Contradictions

US Indebtedness & Capitalism’s Internal Contradictions

US Indebtedness & Capitalism’s Internal Contradictions

US Indebtedness & Capitalism’s Internal Contradictions

Monday, 8th May 2023
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

0:00

This is David Harvey and you're listening

0:02

to the Anti-Capitalist Chronicles, a

0:04

podcast that looks at capitalism through a Marxist

0:06

lens. This podcast is

0:09

made possible by Democracy at

0:11

Work.

0:12

Welcome to this week's edition of the

0:14

Anti-Capitalist Chronicles. As

0:17

usual, I'm deeply indebted to Democracy

0:19

at Work for putting

0:21

this on the air and doing all the work that's

0:24

involved with its production.

0:28

This week, I thought I'd reflect on a

0:30

question I got in an interview I did

0:33

earlier this week. And

0:35

the question was, how come the

0:37

United States ran such a huge

0:40

foreign indebtedness position?

0:45

And what benefits came to the United States

0:47

by virtue of that? My

0:50

instantaneous answer, without really thinking about

0:52

it too much, was that I didn't think the

0:55

United States really did benefit from it

0:57

very much. I then reflected

1:00

a little bit and said afterwards

1:02

that, well, maybe some people in

1:04

the United States benefited from it,

1:06

but the population as a whole

1:09

in the United States certainly did not. And

1:12

then the question that

1:15

followed up was, well, if

1:18

that's the case, why does the United States, with all

1:20

of its power, actually tolerate this situation?

1:22

And my answer was,

1:24

well, I think it was a great

1:28

policy mistake, a

1:30

miscalculation,

1:32

and that there was no intention

1:34

of ending up in this situation. But the fact

1:36

that in 2008, for

1:39

example, the main holders of

1:42

U.S. treasuries were countries like

1:45

China, Russia, Japan,

1:48

and so on, that that was

1:50

a situation which was

1:53

not beneficial at

1:56

all, and that it had arisen for a very simple reason.

1:58

And I think that's what I wanted to say. take the reason,

2:01

the main reason was this. Back in the

2:04

1960s, American corporations were

2:10

protected against foreign competition

2:14

by the structure of the Bretton Woods Agreement,

2:16

which inhibited capital

2:19

controls. The

2:23

relaxation of those capital controls

2:25

with the abandonment of the Bretton

2:28

Woods Agreement in August 15, 1971, that

2:30

that moment meant that the US would have

2:38

to stand up to a foreign competition,

2:41

that the free flow of foreign

2:43

capital coming into the United States or US

2:46

capital flowing abroad, all

2:48

of that changed the name of the game. During

2:51

the 1970s and so, we had a different

2:53

world order

2:55

which emerged

2:57

during those years and has been perpetuated

3:00

in effect to the present time. This

3:03

then was the situation,

3:07

but this raises two questions.

3:09

First, why did the United States

3:11

abandon the Bretton Woods Agreement? The

3:15

answer had to be in part

3:17

because it was inoperative and untenable

3:20

because over the years,

3:21

dollars which were essentially

3:24

controlled

3:25

by the

3:27

US Treasury and the US Central Bank

3:29

were getting

3:31

out of control. There emerged

3:33

something called the Eurodollar market, which

3:36

were

3:36

dollars which were held by European

3:39

banks or by branches of US banks

3:43

in Britain and Europe.

3:45

The Eurodollar market

3:48

meant that a large segment of dollar trade

3:50

was now outside of

3:52

the regulatory apparatus that existed

3:55

in the United States, so that was one aspect

3:57

of it. The second aspect of it

3:59

was, that

4:02

the bankers in the United States, the financial

4:04

interest in the United States, were

4:06

very, very interested in trying to open

4:08

up global trade because they saw many

4:11

opportunities to

4:13

facilitate foreign investment, and for them

4:16

this was very, very profitable. The

4:18

biggest windfall for them came after 1971,

4:21

it came in 1973 to 5, during the Gulf crisis and had a time when

4:32

US capital was having a hard time. A

4:35

large amount of dollars

4:37

was going to the Gulf States,

4:39

and the United States used its

4:41

military power and its diplomatic might

4:44

to insist

4:45

that the Gulf States actually

4:48

invest all that money in the global economy

4:50

via the New York Investment

4:52

Bank. So suddenly the New York Investment

4:55

Banks came flush with a great deal of money, and

4:58

this, or this kind of trade would have

5:00

been impossible under the Bretton Woods Agreement,

5:03

and therefore, what 1971

5:06

did was to open up the possibility

5:08

for a much greater influence over

5:11

public policy of the bankers and so on,

5:13

which then happened.

5:15

But where did the miscalculation

5:18

arise? The miscalculation

5:20

came, I think, because the idea

5:22

was that the US

5:25

corporations and manufacturing industries

5:27

and so on were so good, so

5:30

superb, and so powerful

5:32

that there was no way that they could be bested

5:35

by foreign competition.

5:37

Now, we can go sector

5:39

by sector to see if

5:41

that was really the case, but I think the automobile

5:43

sector

5:44

is the one which is most telling.

5:47

In the 1960s, in

5:49

the United States, there were three auto companies

5:52

that held to an oligopoly

5:54

position. They engaged

5:56

in price leadership, they had, they struck

5:59

the same kind of union contracts and so

6:01

on,

6:01

so that there was a working class

6:04

element involved in how

6:06

those corporations operated. So you had

6:08

Ford, General Motors, Tesla, Chrysler,

6:11

who were essentially the kings

6:14

of the castle

6:18

in terms of the US automobile.

6:21

Of course, the automobile in the United States was

6:23

sacrosanct, and so everybody assumed

6:26

that this whole kind of opening up to foreign

6:28

trade and all the rest of it would

6:30

simply enhance the position of Detroit

6:33

and actually open up

6:35

all kinds of possibilities in foreign markets.

6:38

Well,

6:38

some of that did happen, but

6:42

the reverse happened. By the time you go

6:44

to 1980s,

6:45

suddenly you find that the automobile

6:47

industry in Detroit is under serious

6:50

competitive pressure,

6:51

coming from the then West

6:54

German automobile industry,

6:57

particularly BMW

6:59

and Volkswagen, and

7:01

a great deal was

7:03

also, competition was also coming

7:05

from the Japanese auto

7:08

industry and Toyota

7:11

and so on. So by the

7:13

time you get to the 1980s, Detroit

7:15

is in serious, serious trouble because

7:18

the foreign auto companies are essentially dominating

7:20

the US market.

7:22

And that domination

7:25

was for a particular reason,

7:27

that during the 1960s,

7:30

the automobile industry started to reorganize

7:32

themselves and their leadership

7:34

changed. In the 1950s, 1960s, the

7:36

leadership in the automobile

7:39

industries tended to be drawn from

7:42

deep knowledge of engineering.

7:44

So innovations in

7:47

automobile design and so

7:50

on, and it was very dear to the heart of the engineers

7:52

and so the engineering or

7:54

basis, if you like, of the Detroit

7:56

industry was very strong in the 1960s.

8:00

By the time we get towards the end of the 1960s,

8:02

that leadership has changed. It's

8:05

more and more led

8:07

by financiers and by

8:09

accountants and so

8:11

on. And so the interest

8:14

of Detroit was less and less about

8:16

engineering of cars and more and more about

8:19

making money.

8:20

And so the monetary aspects of things became

8:22

very significant so that

8:25

monetary operations started to be incorporated

8:27

within the Detroit auto companies.

8:30

For example,

8:32

the opening up of

8:33

foreign trade meant that and

8:36

the change in

8:37

currency markets

8:40

meant that you could speculate

8:42

a great deal in foreign exchange

8:45

relations and given that the

8:50

automobile companies had interest in Latin

8:52

America and Europe and so on,

8:54

commodity futures and

8:56

trading in

9:00

foreign exchange futures and so on

9:02

started to become part and parcel integrated

9:04

within the company.

9:06

And in some respects, that

9:09

became even more profitable than making

9:11

cars and it became more of, therefore,

9:14

a greater and greater interest to the Detroit people.

9:16

But the result worth in American cars turned

9:19

out not to be anywhere near as good as the

9:22

Japanese and the West

9:24

German cars. So that, for example, when

9:27

I bought a car in 1987, I didn't even think about buying a

9:31

US made car. You automatically

9:33

thought Toyota or

9:36

Volkswagen or even a Saab

9:39

or Volvo or something of that kind.

9:42

So in effect, the

9:45

policy presumption which had existed in the

9:47

1970s, that the US industrial

9:49

would

9:53

become all conquering, turned

9:56

out to be false. It was the other way around,

9:58

actually, the all conquering old. automobile

10:00

industries in the 1980s were primarily

10:04

Japanese and

10:06

to some extent West German.

10:08

So, what that led to, of

10:10

course, was a bigger impact

10:13

upon the

10:15

trade balance. This

10:17

is the sort of thing that led further

10:19

and further and further

10:21

into the United

10:23

States becoming a debtor

10:25

country in terms of its foreign trade balance.

10:28

Now, this then leads us immediately

10:31

into the kind of question of

10:33

the kinds of things

10:35

that go on in terms of corporate governance.

10:38

And I think in this regard, I

10:40

go back to a book that

10:42

a colleague of mine at Johns Hopkins University

10:45

wrote sometime about now

10:48

called The Cultural Crisis of the

10:50

Firm. And one of the things

10:52

she pointed out was that actually

10:55

firms are not simply run

10:58

by economists and automatons

11:00

who are kind of playing

11:02

the game of economic,

11:04

the perfect economic

11:07

calculator. There

11:09

is a culture to the firm and the culture is

11:12

sometimes misplaced in relationship

11:14

to economics. And there's

11:16

a lot of that bad economic decisions are

11:18

made for cultural reasons and the bad

11:20

economic decisions lead into

11:23

crises in particular firms. So,

11:25

for example, she

11:27

worked a great deal on

11:29

the case of McDonnell Douglas where there were

11:31

some obvious things that needed to be done in

11:33

the face of changing

11:36

defense requirements. But McDonnell

11:39

Douglas failed to do them because

11:42

the culture of

11:44

management and so on was kind of

11:47

set in stone and

11:49

they really couldn't do it for cultural reasons. And

11:51

the result is that the company started to

11:54

fail seriously for economic

11:57

reasons.

11:57

And we've seen this sort of thing going on.

11:59

right as well.

12:01

So this cultural crisis of the

12:04

firm leads into the kind of question

12:06

as to why is it that capital produces

12:09

corporations and practices

12:11

which are actually deleterious

12:14

in the long run,

12:16

both to the macro economy

12:18

in the sense of the trade balance, but also

12:21

in terms of employment and investment

12:24

structures internally, but also deleterious

12:27

even from the standpoint of the company

12:29

itself. A more

12:31

recent example of exactly this problem comes

12:34

up in the semiconductor industry, where 20

12:38

years ago a firm like

12:40

Intel was

12:41

very much in the lead,

12:43

but there were certain kind of innovations

12:45

coming online and Intel was

12:47

comfortable in what it was doing and looked at these

12:50

innovations and said

12:51

it wasn't going to really pursue them because it was going

12:53

to take a lot of extra money and re-engineering

12:56

and re-configuration of what was going

12:58

on in the company. So Intel

13:01

sat there with a very good situation

13:04

at that time,

13:09

but at that time another company,

13:12

which was the Taiwanese company, which is the

13:14

Taiwan Semiconductor

13:17

Manufacturing Corporation, TSMC,

13:21

took up these innovations and started

13:23

to run with them. And by

13:25

the time you get to about 10 years

13:28

ago, TSMC is way, way

13:30

ahead of Intel in terms

13:32

of its

13:35

market share and its profitability

13:37

and its size and all the rest of it. So

13:40

TSMC now is the

13:43

chip maker, which is

13:46

responsible for about 80% of the most

13:48

advanced chips which

13:50

were created with the new technology.

13:53

And Intel is way behind and

13:55

is now actually trying to catch up by spending

13:57

a lot of money,

13:58

billions of dollars to try to do.

13:59

to catch up with the

14:02

Taiwanese companies way, way ahead.

14:04

And here too, it was a company decision

14:07

that

14:07

actually led into this, and it raises

14:09

this kind of question

14:11

of, are

14:14

we going to spend a lot of time praising

14:17

how brilliant the market system

14:19

is and how brilliant American corporations

14:21

are in terms of their management structure,

14:24

and we have plenty of examples of this kind,

14:26

which show that

14:29

in fact the drive, which is supposed

14:31

to be there, is not there for cultural reasons.

14:34

But then there are other answers

14:37

to this question as to why is it that

14:40

capital ends up doing things

14:42

which are actually negative in

14:44

relationship to its own reproduction.

14:47

And this of course is where Marx comes

14:50

in very, very strongly. Whereas

14:53

contemporary economics, generally

14:55

speaking, feels that the market will at

14:57

some point or other

14:58

lead everything to converge into some equilibrium,

15:01

what Marx does is to identify the contradictions

15:03

that lead

15:05

into crises of capitalism and

15:08

what those crises do in relationship

15:11

to output and employment

15:13

and all the rest of it.

15:15

Now there are three ways you can look at this.

15:18

The first way is to say, look

15:20

at it from the standpoint of the individual firm.

15:23

The individual firm will adopt technologies

15:26

which

15:26

further its own particular interests.

15:30

And in adopting those technologies, it

15:32

creates a technological world which may

15:35

actually play a negative

15:37

role in relationship to the future

15:39

of capital accumulation. In

15:41

other words, individual capitalists operating

15:43

in their own self-interest do things

15:45

which in aggregate create a

15:48

negative situation for

15:50

the reproduction of capital. The

15:53

most obvious example of this comes in the

15:55

case of technological change and

15:58

Marx's theory of relative

15:59

of surplus value. Now, I

16:02

encountered this in a sort of discussion I had

16:04

in New Left Review about rates

16:06

and masses where somebody said to me, one

16:09

of the critics wrote and said, well,

16:12

why would an individual capitalist

16:16

engage in technological change when

16:18

that technological change

16:22

raises the productivity of labor

16:24

and that increasing productivity of labor means

16:27

that you employ fewer laborers? And

16:29

if you employ fewer laborers, if you

16:32

take the labor theory of value, then you're going to have

16:34

less surplus value, which means that there's going to

16:36

be a falling rate of profit. So you get the

16:38

thesis of a falling rate of profit

16:40

arising out of rising productivity

16:43

of labor, and that rising productivity

16:45

is powered by individual capitalists adopting

16:48

the innovations.

16:49

Why would somebody do that? Why

16:52

would somebody adopt that technology when

16:54

the output means a falling rate of profit?

16:57

It doesn't make sense. Well, it makes sense

16:59

when you introduce the idea that

17:02

individual capitalists operate in

17:04

the context of what

17:08

Marx calls the coercive laws of competition.

17:11

And the coercive laws of competition are such

17:14

that if I have a better technology than you,

17:16

I'm

17:17

going to get a bit

17:19

of surplus value more than you. So I'm going to

17:21

get higher

17:22

profit rates, and over time,

17:25

I'm likely to drive you out of business because I

17:27

have more surplus value than

17:29

you have.

17:30

The result of that is that the response

17:32

to the coercive laws of competition is that

17:35

if I make an innovation, you're going to

17:37

follow my innovation and catch up with

17:39

me

17:40

and even go beyond me. So

17:42

it is the coercive laws of competition which

17:44

force people to adopt technologies

17:48

which are labor saving and which

17:50

therefore reduce the labor import and which

17:52

therefore have an effect to the falling rate

17:54

of profit. So in other words, there

17:57

is a rational reason why some

17:59

Somebody who has no interest

18:01

in the falling rate of profit will engage in practices

18:04

which actually lead the profit rate to fall.

18:06

This is Marx's argument. In

18:08

this case, we would say it's

18:12

the way in which individual actors

18:15

are supposed to come up with

18:17

technologies and so on which improve their own

18:19

position, but do it in such a way as

18:22

to actually reduce the capacity

18:24

for the reproduction of capital in general. That's

18:27

the first

18:28

part of the story.

18:30

The second part of the story really comes

18:32

out from individual sectors

18:34

in the sense that

18:36

it's hardly as if the energy

18:38

companies feel that they're actually

18:40

duty-bound to behave in such a way as

18:42

to support

18:46

the reproduction of capital accumulation. No,

18:49

they're out there to make a profit and so you

18:52

might find a whole sector

18:53

like fossil fuel sector which

18:56

is going to engage in practices and so on which are

18:58

going to be down to its own benefit which

19:00

will be negative from the standpoint

19:02

of the economy as a whole and certainly negative

19:05

from the standpoint of environmental

19:07

conditions and all the rest of it. Individual

19:10

capitalists operating in their own self-interest

19:12

are part of the problem.

19:14

Sectors or large

19:16

corporations or monopoly groups are

19:20

another reason why the economy

19:23

is likely to drift off in a negative direction

19:26

because each individual sector

19:28

will pursue its own interests and

19:30

in pursuing its own interests will actually

19:33

in some instances support the fee further

19:35

accumulation of capital. In other instances

19:38

subtract from it so that for example

19:40

if we look at what is happening

19:42

in terms of land markets or something of that

19:44

kind, landlord interests can enter

19:47

in, property

19:49

owning factions can enter in, all

19:52

kinds of things like this can happen which

19:54

actually therefore set up

19:56

rational reasons why

19:59

a

19:59

capitalist economy can never advance

20:02

cleanly and purely

20:05

into the future.

20:07

So there are those sorts

20:10

of issues which crop

20:12

up. And I think that actually

20:14

when you start to look at it in the history

20:16

of capitalist corporations

20:18

in the United States, we see many instances

20:21

in which corporations get themselves

20:23

into a mess and go even further.

20:26

So we have things like the Enron debacle

20:28

at the end of 1998. You

20:30

have investment

20:33

speculative crashes

20:36

like long-term capital management in 1998.

20:39

So the point here is that the

20:43

United States became a debtor country,

20:46

not because there was some policy

20:48

decision made that that's a good idea, but

20:50

the center policy decisions were made and

20:52

a set of individual initiatives occurred,

20:55

which actually then forced

20:59

the economy as a whole to move down

21:01

a channel in which the US ends up being

21:03

a debtor country big

21:05

time. And

21:07

now we've sort of stuck with that as

21:10

a fact. Now being a debtor country,

21:12

is that good for

21:15

the United States? Well, of certain people,

21:17

it's very good. Some

21:19

other things I think that

21:22

renders some

21:27

other countries nervous about holding

21:30

American debt is of course, as

21:32

in the case of Russia right now,

21:35

suddenly something goes negative.

21:37

The United States is always in a position to sort

21:40

of sequester all

21:43

the funds that the Russians

21:45

have in US debt and prevent

21:47

their Russians using that debt

21:50

in any way to support their economy. So

21:52

are you coming a bit vulnerable if you hold US

21:55

debt and then the US starts to playing

21:57

games with it,

21:58

but it's very dangerous for the US to.

21:59

to start playing games with it, because then nobody's

22:02

going to buy US debt and take

22:04

up US debt. So you have to be very careful

22:06

about how this works out. But generally

22:08

speaking, Wall Street is quite happy

22:10

to have US hugely indebted

22:13

because Wall Street deals with the

22:15

buy and selling of US debt.

22:17

And of course, that means

22:19

they get all the commissions and all the rest of it. So

22:21

Wall Street

22:25

is not really too perturbed about

22:27

the US debt. On the other

22:29

hand,

22:31

Main Street and the population

22:33

in general

22:34

may find the problem of the US

22:37

debt problematic in the sense that

22:39

it has an effect upon interest rates and

22:42

all the rest of it. So you can start

22:44

to trace back

22:45

lots of good and bad

22:47

effects of being indebted throughout

22:50

the whole of the US economy.

22:52

Now this habit, however,

22:55

of imagining

22:57

that somehow or other US

23:00

capitalism and US capitalist

23:03

corporations somehow

23:05

or other excel

23:08

in their capacities and powers turns out

23:10

to be absolutely not the case.

23:12

And we have all of these examples of

23:14

companies which steer themselves into,

23:18

if not bankruptcy, but into second rate status.

23:21

Intel is now a second rate

23:23

company compared to TSMC.

23:25

And

23:28

there's now this kind of problem

23:31

of exactly how

23:33

to deal with this situation

23:36

given the fact that

23:37

TSMC is a company

23:40

in Taiwan, and Taiwan

23:42

is a problem in the

23:45

sense that it is considered

23:47

by the Chinese to be a province of China

23:50

and considered by everybody else to be

23:52

an autonomous state. And

23:56

the kinds of issues that crop up with

23:58

that, which I think are

23:59

talk about next time. But

24:02

here is, if you like, the main

24:05

thing. Never

24:07

assume that economic rationality

24:10

leads to, at one

24:12

level, conforms to economic

24:15

rationality at another level. When

24:17

Marx talks about the falling rate of profit,

24:19

he's talking about economic rationality

24:23

at the individual firm level,

24:26

which leads to behaviors which

24:28

create

24:29

economic irrationality

24:31

in the macro economy.

24:33

That is going on all

24:35

of the time. When we introduce sectors

24:37

into it and so on, you can

24:39

see immediately that

24:41

this idea that the market is going

24:43

to lead, or economic rationality is going

24:45

to lead to a rational

24:48

result in the form

24:50

of

24:53

an equilibrium economy where everything

24:55

is kind of worked out nice

24:58

and cozy, that is unlikely to be

25:00

the case. Therefore, one is certainly

25:02

going to have signs of economic

25:05

irrationality all over

25:07

the place, which are powered by

25:09

economic rationality at a different level.

25:12

That is one of the major findings

25:15

that Marx has, which says that

25:18

it's the internal contradictions of capital,

25:20

which lead into crises of various

25:22

kinds. The macro economy

25:25

goes down the chute because individual

25:28

capitalists are behaving rationally.

25:31

Therefore, in Marx's

25:33

argument,

25:35

there's nothing essentially leading

25:38

to a rational outcome, leading to

25:40

the major irrationality

25:42

of a crisis,

25:43

the sign of which is that you have surpluses

25:46

of labor,

25:47

surpluses of capital, side

25:49

by side, and seemingly no way

25:51

to put them back together to meet up

25:54

with real, chronic social need.

25:56

This is the situation as it existed in the

25:58

1930s. There

26:00

were massive amounts of unemployed

26:02

population,

26:04

massive amounts of unemployed capital,

26:06

not knowing where they were.

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features