Podchaser Logo
Home
Exploring American Inequality (with Nobel Laureate Angus Deaton)

Exploring American Inequality (with Nobel Laureate Angus Deaton)

Released Tuesday, 14th November 2023
Good episode? Give it some love!
Exploring American Inequality (with Nobel Laureate Angus Deaton)

Exploring American Inequality (with Nobel Laureate Angus Deaton)

Exploring American Inequality (with Nobel Laureate Angus Deaton)

Exploring American Inequality (with Nobel Laureate Angus Deaton)

Tuesday, 14th November 2023
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

3:59

Professor Princeton, now Emeritus,

4:02

which means retired. I'm

4:04

the author most recently of Economics

4:07

in America, an immigrant economist

4:10

explores the land of inequality. But

4:13

I'm also the author with Anne Case of

4:15

three years ago, All Deaths with Despair

4:18

and the Future of Capitalism. And

4:20

before that, a book called The Great Escape.

4:23

Fabulous. Tell us about your new book and what

4:25

inspired you to write it.

4:27

Well, some of the pieces were occasional

4:29

pieces that I'd written over the years. And

4:31

it occurred to me and to Princeton

4:33

Press that they might with a suitable

4:35

amount of work be turned into

4:38

sort of a coherent book. So

4:40

it's partly memoir, sort of about

4:42

me, but also

4:45

memoirs of other economists that

4:47

I've met over the last 40 years. And

4:50

through that, I wanted to give people

4:53

a view of what it was like to

4:55

be an economist, what economists

4:57

do, whether they're really all

4:59

corrupt or whether some of them are actually nice.

5:02

I wanted to talk about some good economics,

5:05

some bad economics. Towards

5:08

the end, I think I

5:10

want to talk a little bit about

5:12

how my profession I think has gone

5:14

a little bit off, maybe more than a little

5:17

bit off the rails. And

5:19

a lot of the problems that

5:21

we face today, especially

5:23

the polarization around

5:25

a lot of very angry, very disillusioned people

5:28

as something, not everything, but

5:30

something to do with the way we practice and

5:33

interpret economics.

5:35

Yeah, so you call America the

5:37

land of inequality. It wasn't

5:40

always this way. There is

5:42

a suspicious correspondence

5:45

between when you came to the United States and

5:47

when it started to get more unequal, I

5:49

should say. I'm thinking of myself

5:51

a little bit before that.

5:59

date of around 1970. And

6:02

also, one of the things

6:05

that I feel very strongly about is that the inequality

6:07

you're referring to there, which is sort of rising

6:10

income and wealth inequality, is extremely

6:12

important. But it's not the only

6:14

sort of inequality that's really important.

6:17

I mean, most Americans, most people

6:19

who talk about these things are certainly equivalent and

6:21

certainly familiar with

6:24

racial inequalities of horrendous

6:26

and long lasting sort. But

6:28

the other inequalities that I've been much

6:31

concerned about is between people who

6:33

do and do not have a four year college

6:35

degree. And the

6:37

terrible outcomes that are besetting

6:39

the two thirds of the population without a college

6:42

degree.

6:43

Right. Now, we talked with

6:45

Michael Sandel a few weeks back

6:47

about that. And I

6:49

know you quote him in the book and you go into this

6:52

in great detail. This is

6:55

really the, as you point out, and

6:58

it started in the mid 1970s,

7:00

this is really the big sort of shift

7:02

that not only has the

7:05

stagnant and declining wages of non-college

7:07

educated, well, men particularly,

7:11

but it's led not just to rising

7:14

inequality, economic

7:16

inequality, but also to this

7:19

degradation of the American political

7:22

system.

7:22

Yes. And also for a lot of people,

7:25

it's a degradation of their communities. Yeah.

7:28

It's a degradation of power,

7:31

which they used to have, perhaps most

7:33

notably through unions, which hardly

7:35

exist anymore. And

7:39

more seriously, perhaps most seriously

7:41

of all, I'm not sure I would put it up there, but somewhat

7:44

declining life expectancy. Yes. In

7:47

a way that's just incredibly unusual.

7:50

Yeah. That part is particularly

7:52

shocking. But can you speak

7:55

a little bit about the

7:57

good, the bad and the ugly of economic inequality?

8:00

economics over the last, over

8:02

the span of your career. You know,

8:04

you have touched so many things.

8:07

You've been awarded a Nobel Prize. You've

8:10

been at the center of the orthodoxy

8:13

and a critic of it. If

8:15

you could, you know, just

8:17

expand on that as you

8:19

reflect on your profession

8:21

and your career. What does it make you

8:23

think and feel?

8:25

Confused,

8:26

I think. Me

8:29

too. Good. Yeah, we're, yeah. It's

8:32

quite hard to be at the center of the mainstream

8:35

and do all these things I've done, like being president of

8:37

the American Economic Association, for instance. But

8:39

compared to the AEA, it's

8:42

always been very diverse. So,

8:44

you know, this was an association that had both

8:46

Milton Friedman and Ken

8:48

Galbraith as presidents. So

8:52

it's never taken a very narrow view of

8:54

things. But come back to the good, the

8:56

bad, and the ugly. I mean, I

8:59

think the gun is, in some ways,

9:01

become much broader. You know, when

9:03

I came here permanently in 1983, it was becoming

9:08

more and more mathematical. It was all concerned

9:11

with general equilibrium theory or with

9:13

macro or with

9:15

micro theory. And there

9:18

were really very few people

9:20

in top universities

9:23

in economics department working on things

9:25

like poverty or inequality,

9:27

let alone race. So

9:30

people do work on these things now. So there's

9:32

been a big broadening of topics.

9:35

We're also very good compared,

9:38

perhaps, with some other social sciences

9:41

at working with data. We can sort

9:43

of count like accountants. And,

9:47

you know, as the world has become more data

9:49

intensive, that has certainly

9:52

opened up lots of avenues

9:53

which have been explored by

9:56

some very good people and with very interesting

9:58

results. The bad

10:01

and the ugly, maybe I can run

10:03

those two together, I'm not even quite sure what

10:05

the distinction is, is

10:08

that economics has

10:11

been very narrow in its focus compared

10:15

with its origins. So if you

10:19

read Adam Smith or Karl Marx or Ricardo

10:23

or John Stuart Mill or even Keynes, there's

10:26

a very broad set of issues,

10:28

including philosophy, some psychology,

10:31

but a serious contemplation of

10:34

the human condition in all its strengths

10:36

and weaknesses and in all

10:39

its dimensions. Whereas

10:41

a lot of economics over the last 20 or 30 years

10:44

has become obsessed with efficiency,

10:47

with the sort of allocation of

10:49

scarce resources among competing

10:52

ends to use Lionel

10:54

Robbins's famous definition. And

10:56

actually I think a lot of economists today, if you

10:58

ask them what economists do, they would say that.

11:01

Whereas other economists have

11:03

had much broader statements. I mean, Pigou had talked

11:06

about being motivated by withered

11:08

minds and mean streets, meaning

11:10

doing something about poverty. Keynes

11:13

talked about efficiency,

11:16

social justice and liberty and

11:19

trying to reconcile those two things.

11:22

We sort of given up on the second two of

11:24

those and seem

11:26

to focus almost entirely on

11:29

efficiency. And that means

11:31

economists have come out against lots

11:33

of things that are really important to ordinary

11:35

people, including minimum

11:37

wages, for instance. We've become

11:40

very in favor of unrestricted

11:43

free trade and free transfers of capital

11:46

around the world. We've become very

11:48

pro-immigration and have not really been

11:50

thinking very hard about whether there might be flaws

11:52

in that case or whether the

11:55

people who worry about it may have a

11:57

legitimate reason to worry about it. And

12:00

so I think we've taken over the political

12:04

and economic discourse in

12:06

a way that has missed a lot of

12:08

really important things and thus contributed

12:11

to the polarization and to

12:13

in some sense the disenfranchisement

12:16

of working people in America.

12:19

Why do you think that that happened?

12:21

Because it's certainly a transformation that has taken

12:23

place over half a

12:26

century more than more. Is it

12:28

something in the broader

12:30

culture or is it something some

12:33

pathology unique to

12:35

economics? Because it really

12:38

seems to function differently than a lot

12:40

of other sciences

12:42

or alleged sciences. Yeah,

12:44

I don't know the answer to that. I mean, there

12:46

clearly are very broad social forces

12:48

going on. So, you

12:51

know, people talk about neoliberalism

12:54

and, you know, the sort

12:57

of eventual retrenchment

12:59

of the New Deal as we move

13:01

back to something that looked much

13:03

more like the Gilded Age with

13:05

both the legal system and the economic system

13:08

and looking like that. And the redistribution

13:11

of power away from labor and

13:14

towards capital, which has swung back

13:16

and forward several times in

13:18

American history. So these broad social forces

13:21

were going on. I think economics

13:23

picked up on that, but also contributed

13:25

to it. You know, the mathematically

13:28

of economics didn't help. Also the fact when

13:30

you think of the huge increase

13:32

in fractions going to college and

13:34

everybody who gets a four year degree has to

13:36

take an economics course somewhere along the way.

13:39

And those economics 101 courses,

13:42

you know, are pretty brutal things

13:45

and I think tend to conform to the

13:49

story I've been telling about focusing

13:51

on efficiency and not much else.

13:53

That raises an important question because we

13:56

have confronted

13:58

other economists before.

13:59

for

14:01

and

14:02

they have said, oh, it's not economics.

14:04

It's, you know, everybody knows that the

14:06

story they tell in the Econ 101

14:08

textbook is, you know, a vast

14:11

simplification and the problem is not

14:13

enough people have gone on to take higher level

14:16

economics to know that what they were taught in

14:18

that first course isn't broadly

14:21

applicable and isn't necessarily true.

14:23

They're just useful fictions

14:25

as Krugman has said.

14:27

Is our problem, and I say our, Nick

14:30

and I, is our problem with

14:32

economics or is it merely with

14:35

introductory economics textbooks?

14:38

So why are the economics, I

14:40

think this idea of this is a

14:43

useful simplification. I just don't buy it all.

14:45

I mean, could you imagine what

14:47

Marx's Econ 101

14:50

would have been? Yeah.

14:54

So, you know, I think that economics 101 has

14:57

done a huge amount of damage. I mean, and there's,

14:59

you know, a group in London that's

15:02

putting together an online

15:04

free textbook which takes very different

15:06

attitudes. And actually, I'm encouraged

15:08

that quite a number of my Princeton colleagues are

15:11

using that text. Yeah, that's Sam

15:13

Bowles' effort, right? Well, it's partly

15:15

Sam Bowles and other people

15:17

at university college, London and so on. So, you

15:20

know, it's a lot of people, but yes, an

15:22

attempt to take a very different

15:24

view of these things. So I think the idea is a useful

15:26

simplification. If you, I mean, the problem

15:29

is most of these people are going to only do

15:32

one course. Yeah.

15:34

So then they go away and go to law school and they

15:36

turn into the Federalist Society or something,

15:39

you know. I mean, that's not really a good way to do

15:41

it. So Angus, you know, one of the things

15:44

that just really

15:48

surprises us is

15:50

the intensity

15:53

of resistance to

15:56

empirical evidence that contravenes

15:59

some of these. ideas. Famously,

16:01

I mean in your book you note

16:04

some of the people who attacked

16:07

Alan Kruger and Andrew Card when they first did

16:09

that first empirical study, James

16:12

Buchanan's famous quote in the

16:14

Wall Street Journal about them being camp following

16:16

horrors and all that stuff. Where

16:19

do you think that anger

16:21

comes from? Like why did it make

16:23

them so angry that

16:25

the empirical evidence seemed to suggest

16:28

that raising wages didn't kill

16:31

jobs?

16:32

Well I tell part of that story. I

16:34

think incidentally I may be the one who

16:37

was responsible for

16:38

finding that Buchanan quote. It's

16:40

in a tiny little addendum in

16:43

buried deep in the Wall Street Journal somewhere.

16:46

It's not you

16:48

know something that's very obvious and I was sort of appalled

16:51

by it at the time. First of all

16:53

it's money you know so a lot of the

16:55

opposition was

16:58

coming from the fast food industry and

17:00

what's it called the employment practices Institute

17:03

or something? Right we call it the

17:05

of the other EPI. The other

17:07

evil EPI.

17:12

And you know it's not obvious when you go

17:14

to the website where the money is coming from but of course

17:16

it is obvious that it's coming from the industry.

17:20

But that's not so surprising

17:22

right after all. You know you

17:24

can expect businesses to defend themselves.

17:27

It actually is somewhat of a confirmation

17:30

of their original case because

17:32

the original case only really makes sense

17:35

if this money is not.

17:38

The truth is that it's coming out of profits not

17:41

causing unemployment right. Right.

17:44

He told me the other day that Buchanan is a textbook

17:46

in which he even says that

17:49

if there's monopsony in the fast

17:51

food market you know then

17:54

increasing wages will actually just cut

17:56

profits. It doesn't cut employment at

17:59

all. least over a modest

18:01

range. Anyway, so it's

18:03

not a surprise that people vested

18:05

interests defend themselves. What

18:08

is a little more disturbing is how many

18:10

economists are happy to line up behind

18:13

them.

18:13

That's what I'm after. And, you know,

18:15

I don't have much to say about

18:17

that. I think there are a lot of people out there

18:20

who are,

18:21

you know, corruptible, if you call

18:23

it that, but they're certainly prepared to

18:26

adopt pleasing positions.

18:29

Yeah. That's where

18:31

the London School of Economics student noticed on his

18:33

door saying pleasing positions

18:35

adopted for cash. But

18:43

surely that's not

18:45

why most economists entered the profession.

18:48

No, that's true. But that doesn't mean they're

18:50

not susceptible

18:52

to the blindishments that come

18:55

their way. You know, and if you ask them about

18:58

those, they'll say things like, I've never

19:00

said anything that I felt the slightest bit

19:02

uncomfortable with, some of which

19:04

traces back to the way they think about economics.

19:07

And, you know, it's clear that most

19:10

economists – well, I'm not going to – I don't want to go

19:12

there. But, you know, money is very tempting.

19:14

To some extent, I came to America because

19:17

I got a much higher salary here, a much

19:19

higher standard of living. And, you know,

19:21

that turned out to be true. So I'm not

19:24

trying to sell myself as a model of virtue.

19:26

And, you know, something that your listeners

19:29

might want to know is this is not a book saying

19:31

Angus Deaton was right and all these other bad guys

19:33

were wrong. You know, it's

19:35

very much a book of how we were all wrong

19:38

or we all over-weighted

19:40

some things and not enough others.

19:42

Yeah, right. So you consider

19:45

yourself a mainstream economist?

19:48

It's not clear that other people do. But,

19:53

yeah, I think so. But,

19:55

I mean, it may be that in recent

19:57

years, maybe I'm just getting old and senile

20:00

or maybe I'm

20:02

a little further distance. Another

20:05

thing that's really important is I grew up in a very different

20:07

place and I talked a little

20:09

bit about that in the book. Where

20:12

I was, my first job was in Cambridge

20:15

in England, a very lowly job as a research assistant.

20:20

That could not be further away

20:22

from Chicago, libertarian

20:25

economics than

20:28

anywhere. I mean that is sort of the

20:30

ultimate opposite in some sense.

20:34

Those people regarded

20:36

Cambridge mass economics

20:38

as the enemy level of people

20:40

in Chicago who were

20:43

pushing libertarian ideas. So they were very

20:45

left wing. John Robinson

20:47

was sort of a Maoist. There

20:49

were a lot of Trotskyists there and so on. A

20:52

lot of them were actively organizing

20:54

communist unions.

20:56

So it was a very different sort of place from

20:59

any sort of American

21:01

department. I think those

21:03

ideas and those feelings

21:06

have stayed with me and they're always

21:08

really there ready to try

21:11

and interpret the world I'm living in today.

21:13

So Angus, I'm not asking

21:16

a rhetorical question. I'm asking a serious question.

21:18

So this podcast is dedicated to

21:22

telling a new story about economics and is

21:24

in many ways an attack

21:27

on what we see is the orthodoxy,

21:31

a bunch of ideas that look to

21:33

us as a protection

21:36

racket for the rich. The

21:39

idea that the economy, for example,

21:41

is a parade of optimal equilibrium, couldn't

21:44

be a more powerful idea to protect

21:47

the status quo. Because

21:49

in that world view, anything you do to mess with it

21:52

decreases the

21:54

efficiency and harms everybody. The

21:56

idea that price equals value, that people are paid

21:58

their marginal product. GDP equals

22:00

welfare. All these ideas, while

22:03

internally consistent and mathematically

22:06

elegant, when taken together

22:08

and taken seriously and

22:11

interpreted into policy, can't

22:14

but create any outcome other than making

22:16

rich people richer and everybody else poorer. Do you

22:19

substantially agree with that?

22:22

Substantially.

22:23

Yeah. And so my question

22:25

is, what advice would you give

22:28

us to be the most

22:31

useful critics of

22:34

the system

22:35

in order to advance a better world?

22:37

Like, you know, if you were our boss, what

22:40

would you tell us to do? That's

22:42

too hard a question. I've

22:47

never been very good at getting other people to

22:49

do things I wanted them to do. And

22:52

I mean, I think that in some ways has helped

22:54

me because I often work alone

22:56

and think alone. But to come

22:58

back to that, I mean, I was

23:01

reading a book by Andrew Koppelman

23:03

the other day about libertarianism, which

23:06

I liked. And it's sort of a critique

23:08

of libertarianism from a socialist from

23:10

a left wing perspective. And

23:13

he very clearly he has a lovely

23:15

phrase, which I can't quite put here, but

23:18

I can't quite remember precisely.

23:20

But it's exactly what you say. I mean, if libertarian

23:24

rhetoric, which is, you

23:26

know, leave the free market, keep government

23:28

out of things in an economy that

23:30

you're pretending is an economy like

23:33

that, an economics 101 economy,

23:36

is simply just a license for plunder. Yeah.

23:40

And that is exactly what

23:42

we have. And I think, you know, I've

23:44

tried for years to track it down. But I

23:46

remember reading Joan Robinson saying,

23:48

you know, American neoclassical

23:51

economics, I guess the term neoliberal

23:53

didn't exist, but you know,

23:56

neoclassical economics is

23:58

an appalloger for America. And

24:02

I wish I could find where she wrote that, but I've

24:04

so far not

24:05

been able to. And even chat GPT

24:07

doesn't seem to be able to fund

24:09

it. Oh, interesting. Well, I substantially

24:12

agree. And there are feedback loop, right?

24:15

I mean, American capitalism didn't always

24:18

view the only purpose of

24:20

the corporation to be – to

24:23

increase corporate profits for

24:25

shareholders, right? That's a relatively new

24:27

invention from the 70s, by the way, from

24:29

economists, right? Well, I

24:32

mean, there were – I mean, it's

24:34

chickens and eggs again, right? Yeah. There

24:39

were very rich people funding those economists

24:41

to spread the Constitution, the

24:43

story of the Moon Peril and society and all

24:46

that sort of stuff. You

24:48

know, as part of it and those people,

24:51

you know. So I

24:53

think Milton Friedman really believed what he thought.

24:56

And, you know, he was happy

24:58

to take money to help push those

25:01

ideas and the business market who funded

25:03

them. But, you know, there have been cycles

25:05

of this, too. I mean, there have been

25:07

earlier periods in the American history where corporations

25:09

were different. And there weren't –

25:12

there wasn't much corporations in the early

25:14

funding days when, as you said, there

25:16

was a large middle class and not very much

25:19

inequality of any kind.

25:21

In your book, you describe – you

25:24

define both conservative

25:27

and progressive mainstream economists

25:30

virtually identically, with

25:32

the exception that progressives are

25:35

more willing to make the big

25:37

trade-off for welfare purposes. I'm

25:40

curious, on the heterodox

25:42

side, outside of the mainstream, where

25:45

do you think the greatest

25:49

opportunities are in the

25:52

evolutionary camp, complexity?

25:55

Just rethinking the things. I'm glad you

25:57

picked that up, incidentally, because I wrote that

25:59

very carefully. And I hope someone would notice.

26:03

Oh, we say the exact same

26:05

thing. So of course I picked up on it. We've

26:08

been saying that about Democrats, that they're just

26:10

as bad as Republicans, they're just willing

26:12

to make that big tradeoff.

26:15

But they think it's there. They didn't used to be. I

26:18

know. There's been a big change.

26:20

That is the big change that's happened is within

26:22

the Democratic Party that sort of moved

26:25

away from a party of working class people. Largely

26:28

supported by unions to become

26:29

a party of

26:32

Econ 101. And

26:35

these educated leads who evolved on Econ 101.

26:38

We call it trickle down light. Okay.

26:44

So that I think is becoming pretty widely understood.

26:47

I'm encouraged by young

26:49

people in the profession who are thinking

26:51

in a very different direction. One

26:53

of the good things about economics is it's very

26:55

open. So you don't have to wait

26:58

until you're 60 years old to get a good

27:00

job in a powerful institution

27:03

when people are changing. And

27:05

there are important people and important

27:07

universities who are challenging the orthodoxy.

27:10

So I saw you to Darren Asmogla

27:12

on the show. Doron

27:15

is goring one of the sacred cows

27:18

of economics, which is that all political

27:20

change is good. Right?

27:22

That's very important work. And he's a very

27:24

important figure and that will really help. And

27:27

I think other people are changing

27:29

too. I mean, Danny Lourdrick's work

27:31

on trade, you know, and

27:33

how the so-called gains for trade are

27:35

tiny compared with the enormous amount of disruptions

27:38

they've done. People have

27:40

identified, you know, Charlie Schultz

27:43

is one of the great apostles of efficiency.

27:47

And you know, that is another

27:49

ox that's been pretty seriously gored. So

27:52

I think I'm, you

27:54

know, at my age, I'm 78 years old. I'm

27:57

not about to change the field. But

27:59

I mean, I do. perhaps exert some influence

28:02

as an elder, but I think there are young

28:04

people picking these things up.

28:06

Yeah, for sure. Do you think it

28:09

can be fixed or is it something

28:12

that the orthodoxy needs to be torn

28:14

down and replaced?

28:15

Well, I don't think it needs to be torn down,

28:18

it just needs to be ignored. Oh,

28:24

okay. Well, you

28:26

know, economics is, if you

28:28

talk to some of the philosophers of science, some

28:31

of them we've worked with who are interested in economics,

28:34

they will point out the fact that economics has multiple

28:36

models, many of which contradict

28:39

one another. So it's like

28:41

you go into a well-stocked store in which

28:43

there are many models there and you

28:46

can pick and choose which ones you want to look

28:49

at, the ones you want to use for a particular

28:51

problem. And the fact that they're mutually

28:53

inconsistent with one another is not really that

28:55

important provided you're

28:57

choosing correctly. And so

29:00

I think that the fact that these things

29:03

will change really

29:06

does make a difference. I mean, after all, I

29:08

mean, you know, Greg Manke taught 101 at

29:10

Harvard or EC1 or whatever,

29:12

EC10 I guess is what it's called. EC10, yeah.

29:14

And then they decided the students

29:17

protested to the point and now it's

29:20

Jason Furman. Like

29:23

one inch better. Yeah,

29:25

and using Manke's book. It's

29:27

a lot better. It may not

29:29

be where you and I would choose to make it go, but

29:32

it's a lot better than it was. And

29:34

you know, that process I think will,

29:36

you know, that's progress and sometimes

29:39

progress is pretty incremental.

29:41

Yeah.

29:42

So I want a definitive answer

29:44

on the titles of the final two

29:47

chapters of the book, which are, did

29:49

economists break the economy and

29:52

is economic failure a failure of economics?

29:56

Yes or no.

29:59

They don't have sole responsibility for breaking

30:02

the E. And that's the story

30:04

that runs through the book. It's a combination

30:06

of bad economics who were prepared and

30:08

a lot of money. And when you put those

30:11

two things together, you can do a lot of harm.

30:13

Yeah. Do we

30:15

always ask in our interviews, a

30:17

benevolent dictator question? I guess

30:20

one form of it would be, if

30:22

you had to do your career over again,

30:25

would you do anything differently?

30:27

I don't know. That's not a benevolent

30:29

dictator question. And one

30:32

of the things you tell your children is that

30:35

decision you're about to make is

30:37

not as important as you think it is, because

30:40

once you're on the other side of it, you'll have no idea

30:42

what it would have been like

30:43

had you done something different. Yeah.

30:46

So I've had a good time. I've learned

30:49

a lot. And I've

30:51

had a lot of recognition for what I do. And

30:54

I wouldn't undo that. But

30:56

I hope that maybe the next generation,

30:59

as I've been talking about, will

31:02

help move the profession in a somewhat different

31:05

direction.

31:06

So if you were a benevolent... Let's get to,

31:08

yeah, the actual benevolent dictator

31:10

question. If you were a benevolent dictator and

31:13

had controls

31:14

over the

31:15

levers

31:17

of policy, knowing what you know about

31:19

economics. And knowing what you know about

31:22

economics in America, the title of

31:24

your book. Yeah. What would you do? I'd

31:26

abolish all the laws that make it hard

31:28

to unionize. Okay. So

31:31

countervailing power. Yes. Let's

31:34

have some countervailing power back again. I

31:36

think that would be the single most important change

31:39

that we could have. And we'd

31:41

have to do it soon, because otherwise,

31:43

you know, I think it's in your title.

31:46

They're going to come for us with pitchfork.

31:48

Yeah. Yeah. No. Okay.

31:50

It's a good answer. Are you encouraged by

31:53

what you're seeing with the UAW strikes

31:55

and the attitudes of the UAW?

31:58

I am. And

31:59

I'm... I'm encouraged.

32:01

We all like to see our work having some effect

32:04

and the work that Anna and I have done

32:06

on deaths of despair has

32:08

moved people so that yes, Janet

32:11

Yellen has been a huge supporter of our

32:13

work since it first came out and talks

32:16

about it frequently. I think

32:18

you know that brings us

32:21

great pleasure

32:22

Yeah, well and the Biden administration

32:24

has broken with

32:27

the last 40 years of neoliberal

32:29

economic policy in a really profound way

32:32

and you know, I think you can take some credit for that.

32:35

Well, thank you. I wasn't

32:38

going to say that but I'm

32:40

very encouraged by that. The question

32:42

of course is just whether it's you

32:45

know green shoots that are about to be sunk

32:47

under an avalanche of money or whether

32:50

it really will rekindle a new future

32:52

and let's hope for the latter.

32:54

And our final question is Why

32:57

do you do this work?

32:59

You probably asked

33:01

my therapist that. I

33:06

mean I grew up pretty poor. We

33:09

worried about money a lot until quite

33:12

late in life even after I

33:14

was by myself. So

33:17

I've always had an

33:20

understanding of that end of things

33:22

I think. I was never desperately poor but

33:26

this sense of worrying about money all the

33:28

time is something that's very very

33:30

bad for people and I wanted

33:32

to understand how that came about and I wanted

33:35

to understand you know, what makes

33:37

people tick and so a lot

33:39

of the early work I did which is you know, very

33:41

mathematical very mainstream and so on

33:44

was still was about that and

33:47

you know, the two people who've had the most

33:49

influence on me

33:50

were Richard Stone who I

33:53

talked about in the book and he

33:55

was one of the great measurers of

33:57

the 20th century. You know, he was interested

33:59

in collecting data describing

34:02

what was going on. And the other was Amartya

34:04

Sen, who I've known almost as long,

34:07

and you know has always had that sort

34:10

of moral compass as part

34:12

of why we do economics. Yeah,

34:14

definitely one of our heroes. Well,

34:18

Angus, we can't

34:20

thank you enough for coming

34:22

on our show. We're huge fans

34:25

of your work. We're just really

34:27

thrilled to get to talk to you, and we

34:30

wish you all the best in

34:32

your future endeavors. We think you still

34:34

will change the profession. We give you more

34:36

credit. I

34:39

think the thing that worries us most about the work

34:41

we're doing now is the sense that many people

34:43

seem to believe there's

34:45

no real crisis at all, and

34:48

you know it's just an opioid crisis,

34:51

or we just got our numbers wrong. And

34:53

you know basically America's

34:56

pretty saddened, and they're jumping

34:58

up and celebrating how well the American

35:01

economy is doing relative to Europe while

35:04

people are dying in droves. Yeah,

35:06

yeah.

35:06

Well sir, thank you so much for being

35:09

with us. Thank you. Yeah,

35:16

Goldie, I was really hoping that Angus

35:18

would give us some really wise

35:20

advice about how to be,

35:23

it was a stretch, an overreach

35:26

in order to get some

35:28

more clarity about what we

35:30

do and how we do it. I think

35:33

you know it is a... But he did. Yeah. He

35:36

simplified it, which is countervailing

35:39

power. Yeah. You need more of that, and

35:42

that's where unions come in. Yeah. I just

35:45

have to ask you, so if you were Angus

35:47

and I asked you that question, would your answer

35:50

have been the same? I know,

35:52

probably not, largely because

35:56

it takes me much longer to drill

35:58

down the core principles. I tried

36:00

to get there, but when I think

36:02

about his answer, what

36:04

he's essentially saying is that when you

36:07

create the conditions for countervailing

36:10

power, it works organically

36:12

in

36:13

the market. As a first principle,

36:16

he's either right or damn near right, correct?

36:18

Right. The thing is, it's really simple

36:21

to do. It's

36:23

not complicated. What you do is

36:26

you make it a hell of a lot easier

36:29

for workers to organize. You support

36:31

organized labor. You take away

36:34

all the restrictions that we've built out

36:36

over the years, and then you

36:38

allow

36:39

organized labor. You allow workers

36:42

to organize

36:44

to

36:45

build their own power to countervail

36:48

the power of employers, and

36:50

you get good things from that. You

36:52

don't have to overthink it. We've

36:54

talked about this a lot, Nick, that what

36:56

we have in our economy

36:59

is a grotesque power

37:02

imbalance that

37:04

is inherent to markets

37:06

operating unfettered. You

37:09

can go all the way back to Adam Smith

37:12

and see that observation. It

37:15

runs through

37:16

classical economics, and

37:18

it actually runs through much

37:21

of

37:21

what became neoclassical

37:23

economics. You see it in Galbraith.

37:26

You see it in Keynes. There

37:28

are different ways of enabling

37:31

and exercising countervailing power,

37:33

but the simplest and the one with the best

37:37

historical support

37:39

is organized labor. You see

37:41

it throughout history that conditions only

37:44

improved when workers were allowed

37:47

to organize. Capitalism

37:50

was not good for the vast majority

37:52

of people until workers were

37:54

able to organize, which by the way was illegal

37:57

for the first century of capitalism.

38:00

It's true. It's true. I think yeah,

38:03

you were hoping and I was hoping for

38:06

a more detailed prescription But

38:08

I think what again the wisdom

38:10

of that answer Is that he understands

38:14

and if you read the book you you understand how

38:16

how complicated the politics is and

38:20

how much money there is on

38:23

the side of capital

38:25

capital and so again A

38:28

lot of capital on the side of capital Right.

38:31

So this is a a very simple

38:33

solution. It's not the only thing you need to do,

38:35

but it would go a A long way

38:38

and again, we we brought it up near the end. You

38:40

see it with the uaw strikes and

38:43

by the way how important just uh

38:45

political leadership is how roundly

38:48

criticized president biden was for

38:51

allegedly violating norms by

38:54

Joining Unbelievable.

38:56

Yeah on the picket line and that's all

38:59

he did Yeah with show

39:01

up there and side with them.

39:03

Yeah, that's all he did and

39:05

a few weeks later You see

39:08

the the strike being settled first ford

39:10

then salantis now gm with

39:13

these big victories for the

39:15

uaw and To

39:18

the uaw leadership's credit They're

39:20

not stopping there because they understand

39:23

if they get these big contract

39:25

concessions out of the big three You're

39:28

just gonna and that's all you do and

39:30

you don't use that as a step towards

39:34

organizing dumler, uh bents

39:36

and Toyota

39:38

and honda and kia

39:41

and everybody else building cars here

39:43

Then you're just going to shift production to yeah

39:46

uh the uh, the so-called Right

39:49

to work states and to non unionized

39:52

plants. So this is

39:54

one step You get this contract

39:56

and now you go to striking you go to autoworker

39:58

zelser and say you could have this too.

40:01

Let's organize and join together." And

40:03

that's what's important. And it's

40:06

big what's happening now. And he's right.

40:08

These may just be green

40:11

shoots that are smothered in the

40:14

collapse of our democracy. That

40:16

could come in the next couple years. But

40:19

hopefully they're not. Yeah. Yeah. I've

40:21

got one other takeaway from this, and that is,

40:23

you know, to point out in the

40:25

book, by the way, his first chapter

40:27

starts with the minimum wage. I know. So

40:29

great. He talks about the $15 wage fight

40:33

in Seattle. And we've

40:35

repeated that before, the Buchanan

40:37

quote, which is one of my favorite quotes

40:40

of all time. Buchanan, by the way, also

40:42

a Nobel Laureate, which is a

40:44

cautionary tale about Nobel Laureate.

40:48

Yeah, yeah, yeah. Half the Nobel Laureates

40:50

in economics were total shitbags. Right.

40:54

So, but it's really

40:56

important when it comes to the

40:58

credibility of mainstream

41:01

macroeconomics in particular and how mathematically

41:04

it's become. When Cardin-Kruger

41:07

did that initial study on minimum

41:10

wage differences in New Jersey and Pennsylvania,

41:13

this difference in difference study and found that

41:16

in fact employment increased

41:18

faster in New Jersey where they raised

41:20

the minimum wage than it did in Pennsylvania.

41:23

And they were roundly criticized. And

41:25

you could understand back then in the

41:28

90s where it's just core

41:30

to orthodox theory that if you raise

41:33

the price of something, people will buy less

41:35

of it. So if

41:35

you raise the minimum wage, employers

41:37

will

41:38

hire fewer people. And they were

41:40

the first to really have

41:42

some study. And you know how these things work.

41:44

There's methodological

41:47

issues all the time, not just in

41:49

economics, but in all the social

41:51

sciences and even

41:53

the hard sciences.

41:55

But it's been decades. It's been

41:58

decades. And the math

41:59

has become more sophisticated, the

42:02

data has become more detailed,

42:05

and decade after decade,

42:07

this finding is confirmed. And

42:09

yet, decades later, only

42:12

about half of economists

42:14

accept these results. There's all this

42:16

empirical data and all

42:19

of this good science, all of this

42:21

good math, and

42:23

these mainstream economists who, you

42:25

know, when I criticize their

42:28

work, I'm often told, well, you just don't understand

42:30

the math, which is true, I don't understand the math.

42:32

I'll admit that, I don't

42:35

understand the math, I can't do it. But

42:38

they understand the math, it's telling them they're

42:40

wrong, and only half of economists

42:42

will accept these results, and I think that speaks

42:45

very poorly to the profession. Yeah,

42:47

absolutely, and, you know, distinguishes

42:49

it from, if I may say so, a

42:52

real science in many ways, where there are

42:54

controversies in physics at the bleeding edge

42:57

of string theory and cosmology

43:01

and so on and so forth. But the simplest

43:03

propositions, like force equals mass times

43:05

acceleration, not controversial.

43:09

Right, and the other thing about science

43:11

is it's not a science if it can't

43:13

be proven wrong. That's

43:16

a religion. Yeah. Well, how

43:18

cool to have Angus on, and

43:20

it's a cool book, and it's in the show

43:22

notes. It's in the show notes again, Economics

43:25

in America, an immigrant economist

43:27

explores the land of inequality.

43:30

I mentioned Angus before we started recording.

43:33

I listened to the audiobook, and I admit

43:36

this, I listen, most of the books I read are

43:38

audiobooks, it's the only way I can get through

43:40

all this stuff. And he reads it himself,

43:43

job well done, but also something I

43:45

hadn't heard in one of these books before. There's

43:48

outtakes, which provide

43:50

a lot of insight, and

43:53

it's just kind of fun to

43:55

hear how an audiobook is

43:57

made, different from the actual design.

44:00

writing it, the reading of it. So highly

44:02

recommend it. Links are

44:04

in the show notes. You can buy this book at

44:06

your local independent bookstore

44:09

or the nameless giant

44:12

monopolist if that is what is most

44:14

convenient for you.

44:27

For

44:30

more information on our website, follow our writing on

44:32

media at civics.org and keep behind the podcast

44:34

scenes on Instagram at Pitchfork Economics.

44:37

As always, from our team at Civic Ventures, thanks

44:39

for listening.

44:41

See

44:41

you next week.

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features