Podchaser Logo
Home
How a New Economics Went Mainstream (with Suzanne Kahn)

How a New Economics Went Mainstream (with Suzanne Kahn)

Released Tuesday, 30th January 2024
Good episode? Give it some love!
How a New Economics Went Mainstream (with Suzanne Kahn)

How a New Economics Went Mainstream (with Suzanne Kahn)

How a New Economics Went Mainstream (with Suzanne Kahn)

How a New Economics Went Mainstream (with Suzanne Kahn)

Tuesday, 30th January 2024
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

0:01

The rising inequality in growing political

0:03

instability that we see today are

0:05

the direct result of decades of

0:07

bad economic theory. It's time to

0:10

build our economy for the bottom

0:12

up of the middle out. Not

0:14

with top down. middle out economics

0:16

is the answer Because was Three

0:18

didn't build this country. Great middle

0:21

class filters country. The more the

0:23

middle class thrives, the better the

0:25

economy is for everyone. Even rich

0:27

people like need. This

0:34

is Pitchfork Economics with Nick A

0:36

An Hour a podcast about how

0:38

to build the economy from and

0:40

middle out. Welcome to the Show.

0:50

So. Goal The It: Today we're

0:52

going to talk to Suzanne

0:54

Khan, who serves as vice

0:56

President at the Roosevelt Institute,

0:58

an organization we work closely

1:00

with, and she's here to

1:02

talk about their new report

1:04

which is called C Change

1:06

How A New Economics went

1:08

mainstream and I think he

1:10

would. I would have a

1:12

lot of. He.

1:15

You know, like we. We were a lot

1:17

to say about the report itself. I think

1:19

our analysis of. The. Sea Change

1:21

would take a different form or I

1:23

mean not new. Well I wouldn't have

1:26

a lap, it would overlap but in

1:28

my saying if we it we'd probably

1:30

give ourselves a little more credit. share.

1:34

An answer. Different kinds of things and

1:36

in a different order and so on

1:38

and so forth. But he here's the

1:40

thing that is one hundred percent correct

1:42

about the report is that there has

1:44

been a sea change. Were in the

1:46

middle of it, right? we are. We

1:48

are in the middle of a have

1:50

a profound sea change. And in

1:52

fact, Nick, You and I, we've

1:54

we've actually been writing about this

1:56

for an upcoming publication. We we

1:58

feel that way. we're

2:00

in a middle-out moment. Yeah but

2:22

what kind of things

2:24

were possible, so on

2:26

and so forth. You know, put aside who

2:29

did what and how it all happened. No

2:32

matter what, it's an extraordinarily

2:35

important and consequential moment. And

2:40

something to be celebrated and

2:43

promoted. And it

2:45

is incredibly consequential, potentially what's

2:47

happening now. Of course, look,

2:52

we don't know how this, how the 2024 election will turn out.

2:55

It could turn out that Trump wins

2:57

and everything the Biden administration has done gets

2:59

thrown out the window, along with all of our democratic

3:01

institutions and norms. And

3:08

that's the end of life as we know it. It could be that Biden

3:10

wins and Trumpsters have an armed rebellion and we get the same thing as

3:12

if Biden lost. Or it

3:14

could be that we have four more years of Joe Biden

3:16

in the White House pushing Bidenomics, which we think is very

3:19

middle-out. And

3:23

it is enough time to complete the paradigm shift that had happened in the early,

3:25

similar to the one that happened in the early 80s when Ronald Reagan, of course,

3:27

was in the early 80s, was in the early 80s. And

3:44

that really ushered in the

3:46

Reagan Revolution, the neoliberal revolution,

3:49

the economic paradigm that we've been living under ever since.

3:54

And this Biden revolution,

3:56

this middle-out revolution could be a

3:58

big part of the world. The. The

4:01

guiding paradigm for the next few

4:03

decades or more. A paradigm which

4:05

we think is better capable of.

4:08

Addressing. Are a crisis

4:10

of economic inequality are are

4:12

Arg, crisis of faith in

4:15

democracy and of course the

4:17

climate crisis which Neo Liberalism

4:19

cannot cannot. It is impossible

4:21

for Neoliberalism to address the

4:24

climate crisis or because it

4:26

will argue that you do

4:28

whatever the market does I

4:31

is the most efficient and

4:33

beneficial and moral and just

4:35

outcome fry. Ah, end of

4:37

the Market. Will never addressed this

4:39

on it's own because as long as

4:41

there is money to be made, By.

4:44

Burning oil and cutting down rain

4:46

forest. then that is what the

4:48

market will do just because they

4:50

have the right to do with

4:52

property rights and encumbered by government

4:54

and all that. so yachts. Anyway,

4:56

you'll be really interesting, talk to

4:58

Suzanne about their report and to

5:00

go through the the elements of

5:02

it and with that let's talk.

5:04

This is at. An

5:10

event on and their Vice President

5:13

of the think Tank at the

5:15

Result Institute. We are a think

5:17

tank that so kisses on changing

5:19

the conversation in which policy has

5:21

made and we work across issue

5:24

areas from climate to corporate power

5:26

at higher education by a common

5:28

theme and all of them is

5:30

kind of move away from neo

5:32

liberal policy paradigms and think about

5:35

new economic policy paradigms. I can

5:37

help us build a more accurate

5:39

a ball economy. And my

5:41

own expertise is really on labor

5:43

and social insurance systems. Ama historian

5:46

by training and night at work

5:48

with I came across a really

5:50

broad portfolio issue areas. Most recently

5:52

I got to work on a

5:55

report we did called. Speech

5:57

zones or bouts of

5:59

every. When it happened over the

6:01

last fifteen years to get us to

6:03

the economic policymaking moment we are now

6:06

and. More. Thanks for joining

6:08

us So regular listeners know that that

6:10

intersection between history and economics. That's my

6:12

sweet spot. That's what I love to

6:14

talk about so it's great to have

6:17

you on the pod Nick You want

6:19

to start off? Sure, I mean so

6:21

you've got to see report out once.

6:23

You kind of give us some the

6:26

top. Set. Sell Out

6:28

We called it see to ends

6:30

And because it is really about

6:32

what a huge change has occurred

6:35

over the last fifteen years, years

6:37

or so in that and shared

6:39

common sense in which policymakers make

6:41

economic policy. I know this is

6:44

something you all have talk about

6:46

on previous episodes but again. What

6:48

we were really wanted. To document

6:50

and look out was how different

6:53

the for policy making landscape is

6:55

now and then it was. Even.

6:58

Honestly, four years ago you will

7:00

during the Obama administration right during

7:03

the about an assertion that Trump

7:05

administration. And we really wanted

7:07

to trace out what had happened to

7:09

get us to this moment. And.

7:11

How we got to a point where policies

7:14

that were. Unimaginable.

7:16

Eight. Years ago. For years ago. Everything

7:18

from how Biden responded to the.

7:20

Coven. Nineteen Recession within massive investment

7:23

and actually spending money and

7:25

not austerity policies to the

7:27

climate policies in the Ira,

7:29

to his willingness to train

7:31

council seat and Dad are

7:33

all with a representative of

7:35

a much larger shaft away

7:37

away from thinking about policymaking

7:39

as something that should happen

7:41

with markets as a central

7:43

frame. So. That was that. sort of

7:45

the top. My number one and then I would

7:47

say toppling number two is. We. Are in

7:49

as. Gary. Moment we don't

7:52

know why or place the

7:54

neoliberal assumptions of the past,

7:56

we at Roosevelt certainly are

7:58

proposing that new. frameworks that

8:00

would move us in a more

8:02

progressive direction that center equity

8:04

and concern for our climate.

8:07

But where we're going next is up

8:09

for grabs and we thought that a

8:11

first step to helping direct

8:14

that was to document how far we've come

8:16

which can hopefully give us the momentum in

8:18

that progressive direction. So

8:20

I mean what are the

8:22

high points? Or you could you

8:24

could also start from the low points to the

8:26

high points where we were 15 years ago to

8:29

where we are now. It is quite remarkable.

8:31

Yeah. Well I'll say

8:33

our joke sort of like internal

8:35

joking title for this before

8:37

we released it was Millennials

8:40

Now Old. And we

8:42

really felt like as we were writing it this

8:44

was a story about the lessons a whole generation

8:46

of people learned from living through the economic crisis

8:49

of 2008-2009 and sort of the long 10 years

8:51

after that.

8:57

So we started a lot of

8:59

the story with Occupy Wall Street

9:01

as a response to the neoliberal

9:03

framework with which the economic crisis

9:05

was met and really

9:07

tried to show how the groundwork was laid

9:09

on a whole range of issues. I think

9:12

it's fair to say no one really

9:14

expected in during the presidential

9:16

primary of 2020 that

9:20

Biden would be the guy who like

9:23

made all

9:25

of these or made many

9:27

of those ideas become at

9:29

least partial realities that

9:32

had been ideas that had been

9:34

coming up from movements and economists

9:36

and think tanks on really pushing

9:38

the edge of pushing against

9:40

neoliberalism for you know the past 10 or

9:42

so years but the world

9:45

changed so fast that the

9:47

Biden-Omics agenda has really a

9:49

reflected many of those lessons

9:51

that I think were started

9:54

to be learned and thought through in

9:56

the wake of that 2009 recession. One

9:58

of the advantages to having an 80 year

10:01

old president is that Joe

10:04

Biden actually was elected to

10:06

the Senate before neoliberalism took

10:09

hold. So he's old

10:11

enough to remember what it was like

10:13

before neoliberalism and what type of policies

10:15

we had back then. Yes,

10:17

even older than the millennials who are now older. Yes.

10:21

So let's talk about some of these

10:23

policies and how they're different. I'm also

10:26

curious, not just from the

10:28

policy perspective, but how the

10:30

economic thinking that underlies

10:32

and informs these policies

10:35

has changed. Yeah, absolutely.

10:37

I mean, one of my favorite

10:39

examples is actually student debt. I

10:42

think you can really trace

10:44

an interesting arc from, again, Occupy

10:47

Wall Street all the way through to

10:50

Biden ultimately trying to cancel student debt.

10:52

We can put the Supreme Court aside

10:54

for a second. But one

10:56

of the things that really comes

10:58

up during the Occupy moment is

11:00

challenges to how

11:03

much debt people are holding across a whole or

11:05

for a whole variety of reasons and really

11:07

challenging that. But the challenge to

11:09

student debt gets really institutionalized. A

11:12

bunch of organizations, including the debt

11:14

collective, are formed out of

11:16

the initial Occupy moment. And

11:18

they really start to put together a

11:20

challenge to the idea that higher education

11:23

should be paid for in this

11:25

way, which is to say buy

11:27

individuals using private financing, which

11:30

was really sort of the

11:32

product of neo-liberal policy ideas

11:35

that said we're

11:37

all individuals who compete in a market.

11:39

We all have our own personal

11:42

human capital to invest in. And

11:45

investing in higher education for ourselves will

11:48

be a good investment that prepares us

11:50

to be little market actors who are

11:52

going out into an equitable, like a

11:54

free market and we're just all going to compete

11:56

from an equal starting platform. So I think over the course

11:59

of the. the 2020, the 2010s, you really see a growing

12:01

challenge to this, this neoliberal

12:06

idea about human capital, underlying,

12:10

like growing movement for free college and debt cancellation,

12:12

UC Bernie Sanders pick it up in the 2016

12:15

campaign. And then

12:17

by the 2020 Democratic primary, sort

12:20

of all the candidates are fighting

12:22

for who has the most progressive free college

12:25

and debt cancellation plan. And

12:27

one of the results of that is that

12:30

when the COVID-19

12:32

pandemic starts, and there are

12:35

sort of looking around for

12:37

ways to get money back into people's

12:39

pockets and stimulate the economy, student debt

12:41

payments get paused, which I don't think would

12:44

have happened without that eight years of work,

12:46

putting that idea forward. And

12:49

it creates a momentum of its own. So

12:51

that when you know, when Biden comes in

12:53

into office, people have not been paying student

12:55

debt payments for months that continues. And ultimately,

12:57

we see him try

13:00

and cancel student debt and make

13:02

major reforms to the way that

13:04

payment systems work going forward as

13:06

well. Right. And it's interesting, because

13:08

when you look at opposition to

13:10

student debt forgiveness, it's

13:12

often presented as like totally

13:15

outside the norm that somehow

13:17

we're going to take this large group of

13:19

people and say, Oh, you don't have to

13:22

pay your debt and that that is un-American

13:24

in some way. But really, it's the student

13:26

debt itself that is the historical anomaly. Our

13:29

entire public education system,

13:31

both K-12 and

13:34

public colleges and universities,

13:37

was founded on

13:39

the notion that a

13:41

well-educated, skilled workforce was

13:44

a public good, not

13:47

private, personal owned

13:50

human capital. But it's a

13:52

public good it was advocated for

13:54

by industry because they knew they

13:56

needed a Literate and

13:58

numerous workforce. I. In

14:01

a modern economy and it's the neo liberal

14:03

era where we say no, no, no, that's

14:05

a private good you should pay for yourself.

14:08

That's the historical anomaly. So.

14:10

It Again, It's it's. In some

14:12

ways, it's fascinating to see this start

14:14

to shift back to what it had

14:17

been for The. Their. Previous

14:19

Hundred and fifty years. The

14:21

I I completely agree and I think

14:23

you know where result that a lot

14:25

of work and the twenty and and

14:27

twenty eighteen twenty nine pm. Looking at

14:29

all the different ways that that idea

14:31

about human capital had. Been.

14:34

Miss understood And so we have

14:36

a great paper about House. Actually,

14:38

employers are just demanding more and

14:40

more credentials for the same jobs

14:42

and seven several her pet hates.

14:44

It's not that you're actually investing

14:46

ourselves. And aware that is getting new. Near.

14:48

Recovery know, growing your i guess

14:51

returns on investment and more as

14:53

and killer even more damningly employers.

14:55

Are demanding many more degrees for

14:57

the same jobs from. Black. Applicants

15:00

than from what. We.

15:02

See that their study showing that as

15:04

sir. Unemployment goes up

15:06

ah employers demand more credentials

15:08

as the labor market titans,

15:10

and it's harder for them

15:12

to find workers. They demand

15:14

fewer for dungeon. So

15:17

it's a market power. Issue

15:19

is so Speaking of market power, What? What

15:21

are we talking for? Little bit or suzanne

15:23

about promoting competition. Tickets. To that.

15:26

I think another thing you see

15:28

over the course of the twenties

15:30

handles a growing sense. That.

15:33

That is. Very. Large

15:35

companies like Alice has

15:37

adding more and more

15:40

control over Alive and

15:42

are. being allowed to

15:44

grow and self absorbed and

15:46

competitors and because of the

15:48

way we've come to understand

15:50

competition policy and any trust

15:52

law and one of the

15:54

another big chef that you

15:57

see abiding messrs in implementing

15:59

as appointing Lena Kahn, who

16:01

was one of the leading critics of

16:03

corporate concentration and as founder of

16:05

the Neo-Brandisian School

16:08

of Antitrust to

16:10

run the FTC. And so we

16:12

see them really centering an idea

16:15

around needing more competition

16:17

and really taking on corporate concentration,

16:19

which I think is a larger

16:22

part of, it's obviously its own pillar

16:24

of binomics, but I think, but

16:27

across the board, one

16:29

of the breaks with neoliberalism that

16:31

is really significant that we're seeing

16:34

is an understanding of power

16:36

and really trying to understand how power is

16:38

playing out, whether it's in labor

16:40

markets or among companies

16:43

or in shaping public policy and

16:45

the competition policy is part of

16:47

that. Right. And that is

16:50

really kind of a core feature

16:52

of neoliberalism is wishing

16:54

away power, I think knowingly

16:57

because it's an

16:59

ideology created to benefit people

17:02

who have lots of powers. You

17:04

want to pretend it doesn't exist.

17:06

But it's actually deep it deeper

17:08

than the weaponized ideological framework of

17:10

neoliberalism powers wished away and,

17:13

you know, in neoclassical economics, right?

17:15

Like the problem is deeper and

17:17

worse, because you can't make the

17:19

math work if power exists, right,

17:23

in these equilibrium systems, you

17:25

know, you have to assume power away.

17:27

How do you magnetize power? Yeah, exactly.

17:29

It's very difficult. And, you know, if

17:32

you desperate to believe that markets are

17:34

perfectly efficient, and people are perfectly selfish

17:36

and rational, and, you

17:38

know, the economy is pretty optimal, power

17:40

is very awkward. And ignoring

17:43

power in economics would be like

17:45

ignoring gravity in physics. You

17:48

know, like you're missing the big part. And

17:52

obviously, one of the most exciting

17:54

things about the Biden administration is

17:56

their Head on approach to

17:59

this problem. And if.

18:01

We can get another four years.

18:03

Probably the most important legacy may

18:05

be maybe the these executive orders

18:07

that are trying to make markets

18:09

truly competitive rather than the oligopolies

18:11

said. They mostly are just really.

18:14

Really? Exciting. A non

18:16

serious suzanne, we have a take

18:18

on this, but whether you and

18:20

your colleagues see a coherent narrative

18:23

in. By. Dynamics' and

18:25

it's three court stated. Their.

18:27

Their self self proclaimed

18:30

three pillars of empowering

18:32

workers. Making smart

18:35

investments and promoting competition.

18:37

Dcs coherent economic narrative

18:39

in that. Ideal.

18:41

And so we all have thoughts about

18:44

how well that narrative beg. Present.

18:46

Add but I think a especially for

18:48

sounds like you I need a who

18:51

have been thinking a lot about Neo

18:53

Liberal As an end? it's coherent narrative,

18:55

the three pillars into. All.

18:58

Take. On the idea that.

19:01

Marquette, Are. The

19:03

primary frame through which

19:05

public policy. And

19:08

that the government's role as flat markets. The

19:10

markets. And

19:12

I'm Amy. I think it all goes

19:14

back to that power peace words are

19:16

talking about In I think they're all

19:18

trying to look at. how do we.

19:21

Shift who or what companies have

19:23

power and actually say there's a

19:26

role for the government and to

19:28

play in. Choosing. Who

19:30

we want to have power and how we want

19:33

them to have power in his Around these different

19:35

issues we need at all. right? And

19:37

and and and Reap Balancing

19:39

that power imbalance mean that

19:41

is you know is implicit

19:44

in their pillars of empowering

19:46

workers. It's it's it's to

19:48

use government to either provide

19:50

or to enable. ah, this

19:53

countervailing power in a segment

19:55

of the market which is

19:57

No even Adam Smith acknowledged.

20:00

is leans in favor of the

20:02

employer. That

20:04

workers are naturally, individual workers

20:06

are naturally at a disadvantage

20:08

in terms of their

20:10

power relationship with their employer. This

20:13

is very different from the neoliberal approach

20:15

of, oh, just let the markets

20:17

work it all out and we'll end up with

20:20

an efficient and fair outcome because that's how markets

20:22

always work. Yeah. And

20:24

everyone has equal power in the system. Let's

20:27

get to some of the specifics

20:29

of this report in terms of

20:32

what has led to these changes

20:34

both in policy and theory.

20:36

Obviously, we've got two

20:38

big ones, which kind of bookend

20:41

this, which is the financial

20:43

collapse, the great recession

20:45

and that long, painful,

20:47

slow growth recovery. And

20:49

then on the other end, the pandemic. But

20:52

there's a lot of things that

20:54

happened in between and Nick and

20:57

I were chatting before you joined

20:59

us. And one of the

21:01

things we noticed was missing from the

21:03

report was a mention of the Fight

21:05

for 15 and the success

21:07

of these minimum

21:10

wage movements in cities

21:12

and states around the country. I'm

21:14

curious how whether you feel

21:16

the fight for a minimum

21:18

wage kind of changed the way

21:20

people think about economics and

21:22

also if you want to go through some

21:25

of the other things that helped

21:27

brought us to this moment. That's

21:29

a great point about the Fight for 15. I

21:32

think we really tried to

21:34

pick a few examples

21:36

kind of within each pillar to

21:38

chart. I do think it'd

21:41

be interesting to think about where the Fight

21:43

for 15 would fit in there. I

21:46

certainly think it's part of the empower and educate

21:48

workers track. I absolutely do think

21:50

the Fight for 15 was a significant

21:52

moment. I think a lot of

21:54

the Biden administration's biggest successes

21:57

around worker empowerment.

22:00

have really come back actually to the

22:03

ARP and the decision

22:05

to prioritize full employment

22:07

over, in some ways, inflation.

22:13

We don't talk enough about how

22:15

that has really allowed for the

22:17

wave of strikes and empowerment of

22:19

workers as sort of a generational

22:21

high. So I think that we were

22:24

focused on that piece of the story and Fight for

22:26

15 is probably more related to

22:28

some of the unfinished business, but I

22:30

think there's still a lot of work

22:32

to do to reform our labor laws

22:35

at the national level. I think what we would

22:37

tell you is that we always viewed it as

22:39

a wedge issue. That the Fight

22:41

for 15 was both

22:43

good policy in that it

22:46

has. Clearly, the study show

22:48

it's had a huge

22:50

impact on people's lives in terms

22:52

of raising wages at the

22:55

low and even pushing up a bit as

22:59

people above minimum wage

23:01

jobs rise in response. But it also I

23:03

think has done a great job not just

23:06

just of educating workers as

23:08

to, hey, we can win something

23:10

like this. But I think pundits,

23:12

journalists, economists, the fact that it

23:15

called the lie on

23:17

one of the core principles, not

23:19

just of neoliberalism, but of neoclassical

23:21

economics, that when the price of

23:23

something rises, people purchase less of

23:26

it. That the labor

23:28

market is somehow locked into

23:30

the law of supply and demand. That

23:33

if you raise the minimum wage, employers

23:36

will hire fewer low wage

23:38

workers and that has turned

23:40

out not to be

23:42

true. Again and again, either there's no

23:44

correlation the study show or

23:47

in fact that recent study showing

23:49

that the higher the minimum wage

23:51

went, the larger the increase

23:53

in employment locally. To us, we

23:57

think this is just it calls the lie

23:59

on Orthodox economics entirely because if

24:01

they're wrong about something as basic as

24:03

that, what else are they

24:06

wrong about? Yeah, it feels to us

24:08

like the $15 minimum wage was the

24:10

first big assault on neoliberalism because

24:12

the Orthodox thinking was when you raise

24:14

wages, it kills jobs. And

24:17

the degree to which that idea

24:19

got embedded in policymaking explains

24:23

probably a trillion or a trillion and

24:25

a half dollars of the trillion of

24:28

the two and a half trillion dollar

24:30

shift in income from the bottom 90% to the top 1%.

24:36

All of these things I think

24:38

together combine to shake the sort

24:41

of neoliberal and neoclassical way of

24:43

understanding economic cause and effect which

24:45

makes things like canceling student debt,

24:48

promoting competition, all that other stuff

24:51

seem more logical and plausible. I

24:53

mean the title of your report

24:55

I think is really spot on

24:57

which is sea change. Right,

25:00

it is a profound change in

25:04

how policymakers see economic

25:06

cause and effect and

25:09

I think what's really

25:12

remarkable is that we had eight

25:14

years of the Democratic administration not

25:16

very long ago that had

25:18

the political power to do all the stuff

25:20

that the Biden administration has done but just

25:22

chose not to do it because

25:24

the economists that were running that

25:26

policy shop thought that all of

25:28

those things would be a big

25:30

government job killing attack on freedom.

25:33

Right, and kudos by the way to Roosevelt which played

25:35

a big role in

25:37

making sure those guys didn't get their

25:39

jobs back. That's right. The

25:43

old, I'd

25:46

say that personnel is

25:48

policy and Roosevelt played

25:51

a big role in helping the staff,

25:53

the recommending

25:56

staff for the Biden administration

25:58

so it's a much better better

26:00

personnel than we've had in the past. Yeah,

26:02

we're very proud of that. And I think, I

26:04

mean, I do think that the, you

26:07

know, you asked what are the things

26:09

that change and I do think that

26:11

the experience of sort of

26:13

the promise of the Obama administration, I

26:16

worked on that campaign, I remember

26:18

the excitement of the

26:20

election and then the, I think there

26:22

was a visceral experience of the sort

26:25

of grip neoliberalism actually had on all

26:28

policy imagination that occurred over

26:31

those eight years that are part of what

26:33

laid the groundwork for this sea change. No,

26:35

I would add to that, you know, an accelerating

26:37

climate crisis as well. And for

26:39

the Trump administration. Yes. Well, and then

26:41

there's the, but in some ways I

26:43

think that's a different visceral experience. Let's

26:47

be fair to Obama. It's not his fault

26:49

that he was so young. Look,

26:52

do I generally think our

26:54

president should be in their 80s? No.

26:59

But, but it's not again,

27:01

I repeat this a lot. It's not

27:04

all bad, especially in

27:06

this moment when you have somebody with

27:08

the long life of

27:11

experience to know that there are other ways of

27:13

doing things than the way we've been doing it

27:15

for the past 40 years. So

27:18

a couple of final questions. The first is

27:20

our benevolent dictator question. So if you were

27:22

in charge of everything, what would

27:24

you do? We

27:27

at Roosevelt, because I think so much

27:29

of our work is about the paradigm

27:31

level and trying to shift the conversation.

27:33

We spend a lot of time thinking

27:35

about what a different policy world would

27:37

look like. But I

27:40

think we start to fail at our job when

27:42

we reject all political constraints. And

27:44

I'll, and I will tell you why I think we,

27:46

and, you know, I can imagine the best of all

27:48

possible worlds, but when we measure ourselves against that, it

27:50

becomes really hard to celebrate our wins. And I do

27:52

think part of our, of the point

27:54

of this paper was

27:57

not to say, you know, everything's great and we've, we

27:59

did it all. but to say, look how far we

28:01

have come, and it

28:03

is really important for building

28:05

momentum that we recognize that.

28:08

Yeah, absolutely. And one final

28:10

question, why do you do this work? I

28:12

have worked for labor unions, I've worked on

28:15

like much more direct policy fights. And

28:17

I think sometimes it can feel a little

28:20

silly to focus at this high a level

28:22

around and really be trying

28:24

to think through the conversation in which policy is

28:26

made. But on the other hand, I do think

28:28

we are at this moment where people

28:31

are questioning neoliberalism

28:33

in a way, and the sort of

28:36

dominant policy frame in a way that

28:38

has not happened in 30, 40

28:40

years. And

28:42

that's an incredible moment of opportunity. But it's

28:44

also a moment where we don't know what's going

28:47

to happen. We don't know if the answer,

28:49

if the new frame is going to lead

28:51

us towards more climate catastrophe or less, whether it's

28:53

going to make the air safer to breathe,

28:56

or less safe to breathe, if it's going to

28:58

make people have more opportunity no matter where they

29:00

come from, or less. And

29:03

I really think we at a moment when things are

29:05

up for grabs, it's so important

29:07

that we are trying to ensure

29:10

and putting forward a vision that

29:12

can shape a whole

29:14

range of public policies that move us in

29:16

a more progressive direction. Awesome.

29:19

Well, thank you very much for being with us. Yeah,

29:21

thank you. Of

29:28

course, Nick, listening to

29:30

Suzanne, I was reminded

29:32

of one of our

29:34

great American economists, Milton

29:37

Friedman, who

29:40

is responsible for much of this, but

29:42

also was absolutely right on at least

29:44

one point. And

29:47

I remember this quote very clearly, only

29:50

a crisis, actual or perceived,

29:53

produces real change. When

29:55

that crisis occurs, the actions that

29:57

are taken depend on the the

30:00

ideas that are lying around.

30:03

Yeah, it could have been more

30:05

right. That was Milton

30:07

Friedman on the

30:09

ascendancy of neoliberalism, that

30:12

they pushed these ideas for

30:15

several decades. And when that

30:18

crisis, the stagflation, occurred

30:20

in the 1970s, and the Keynesians seemed

30:24

to be unable to come up with

30:27

policies to address it, Friedman

30:30

and his fellow neoliberals swooped

30:32

in with their

30:34

ideas that were lying

30:36

around. And the neoliberal

30:39

era was the result. Yeah,

30:42

absolutely. And here we are in a

30:44

new era, and there's a bunch of

30:46

new ideas that are percolating in a

30:48

really profound way. And we'll

30:50

have, I think, a really

30:53

big effect on

30:55

the economy, and ideally how people think

30:57

about how the economy works. One

31:00

of the final things that Suzanne said was

31:02

that we don't know what's

31:05

going to happen. And I agree in the

31:07

sense that we don't know

31:09

whether this new paradigm will be

31:11

given the opportunity to take hold. But

31:14

I think there are a lot of things that

31:16

we do know about what that, if

31:19

it does take hold, what that new paradigm will

31:21

look like. Because there's

31:23

been a lot of advances

31:25

in economics just

31:29

the science of it over the past

31:31

few decades that informed that

31:34

middle out, Bidenomics paradigm.

31:37

There's a lot of empirical evidence that

31:39

supports it. And I

31:42

think one of the things that you and

31:44

I have played a role in over the

31:46

past decade is the narrative

31:49

has advanced. And we

31:51

are a storytelling species, and

31:53

having a good story to

31:55

tell is really important. Yep,

31:57

absolutely. We're telling a better

31:59

story. and it's catching on. That's right

32:01

and you know the good news is Goldie

32:03

is that no matter what happens the

32:06

state of the art in economics has

32:08

changed. I mean the Heritage Foundation is

32:10

never going to change right. The Cato

32:12

Institute is never going to change but

32:15

the better economic

32:19

ideas that are emerging

32:21

from the Academy the fact

32:24

that there's an empirical revolution

32:26

going on in academic economics.

32:28

We're not just talking about

32:30

some dumb theory we're actually

32:32

checking what happens in the real world

32:35

to figure out if the theory makes

32:37

any sense or not. You

32:39

know those trends I think are

32:41

not going to stop they're going to accelerate. You know

32:44

I think there's a broad awareness

32:46

within the academic economics community that a

32:48

lot of the stuff that they said

32:50

was true wasn't and so

32:53

I do think that they're you know obviously

32:55

the world's at a very scary point but

32:57

I do think that long term the

33:00

paradigm will shift. The question

33:02

is are we going to make a lot of

33:04

progress soon or is that progress going to be

33:06

slow and fitful and are we going to have

33:08

to take two steps backwards or ten steps backwards

33:10

to take one step forward. That

33:12

remains the question. And I think one

33:14

of the things that's encouraging to me

33:17

about this is you know as

33:19

Suzanne said that their joke

33:22

title was what Millennials Get Old and

33:25

it's important to note that Millennials

33:27

who graduated into the job market

33:30

in the mid-aughts into the

33:33

depths of the Great Recession

33:35

and that slow recovery they

33:37

really suffered from neoliberal policies

33:39

and neoclassical economic theory. They

33:41

were the victims of it.

33:44

A lot of the losses that occurred

33:46

to them will never be fully regained.

33:49

These are people whose

33:52

lifetime job earnings will

33:54

never recover fully whose

33:56

Net Worth will never recover fully

33:59

from that. The last decade

34:01

a post Great recession

34:03

and and that last

34:06

decade was. A consequence

34:08

of bad policies and

34:10

contrast that which what

34:13

happened with the pandemic

34:15

which was a. Much.

34:18

Bigger. Economic. Collapse

34:20

than anything we saw during

34:22

the Great Recession. I mean,

34:24

people have to remind themselves

34:27

said the spike in unemployment.

34:29

Or during the pandemic. Is

34:32

so huge that we're going to have

34:34

to just. You. Know skipping over

34:36

a thing to future of have

34:38

a set of six. the graphs

34:40

won't fit on the page or

34:42

me and we're talking likes magnitudes

34:44

greater than anything we've ever seen

34:46

in history, ever young. and to

34:48

have a disruption like that and

34:50

to come out of it. As

34:53

well as we had in fact in

34:55

some cases many for many people better

34:58

with higher incomes and more savings and

35:00

they had before the pandemic and then

35:02

to have that that spike have club

35:04

loved i know you hate to call

35:07

it inflation, higher prices that you know,

35:09

spike of higher prices that we had

35:11

and to be told all now we're

35:14

gonna have to have some suffering to

35:16

deal with this for gonna have to

35:18

have seven and a half unemployment for

35:20

two years. Go back to the bad.

35:23

Times that turns out we

35:25

didn't love. This shows you.

35:27

Oh My. God. Government is

35:29

not the problem. It can

35:32

be the solution and all

35:34

that government spending. Actually

35:36

paid off. Ah,

35:39

A in terms survey, easing the

35:41

transition into the pandemics and out

35:43

of the pandemic and into this.

35:46

The. Historically strong labor market that

35:49

we have today. So.

35:52

There you had a real life experiment.

35:54

Your if you look at the millennials.

35:56

They went through the neoliberal policies following

35:58

the great research and they are. No,

36:00

we can't We can't spend too much.

36:02

We have to of austerity. That's the

36:04

way to get out of this and

36:06

ten years of suffering and then we

36:08

have. The. Non and

36:10

neo liberal almost keynesian

36:13

approach. To. Their

36:15

pandemic and oh my god

36:17

to with some added this

36:19

sarah so much quicker and

36:21

better from an even steeper

36:23

decline. There's lessons to be

36:26

learned from real life. Yeah, Let's.

36:28

Hope we learn the lessons that that the. but the

36:30

problem with humanities were so bad at that. Well.

36:32

Again, to tell the story right. People

36:35

need to know. The people need to

36:37

know. They need to stop focusing on

36:39

one year of inflation. Of

36:41

higher prices which was very

36:44

volatile. Clearly. A

36:46

supply side problem. Stop. Focusing

36:48

on that and look at how

36:50

your real wages are higher than

36:52

they were before those prices went

36:54

up. And how much better off

36:56

you are coming out of the pandemic

36:59

then you were coming out of the

37:01

Great Recession and Man by Dynamics' starts

37:03

to look pretty good. Absolutely.

37:06

Again, If you wanna read the

37:08

full report sea Change how a New

37:10

Economics went mainstream, there is a link

37:12

in the show Notes: To

37:20

studies and civic center of you want to sell

37:22

and actual of start me on the deal for

37:24

you that your. And

37:26

us on Twitter and Facebook at Syntax

37:28

and and they can. Our fall are

37:30

riding on medium. it's a Skunk works

37:32

and people in the podcast scenes on

37:34

Instagram at Pitchfork Economics has always some

37:36

our team. It's adventures. Sing soliciting.

37:40

See. An exit.

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features