Podchaser Logo
Home
Artificial Intelligence and the next Industrial Revolution with Professor Nicholas Crafts

Artificial Intelligence and the next Industrial Revolution with Professor Nicholas Crafts

Released Thursday, 11th May 2023
Good episode? Give it some love!
Artificial Intelligence and the next Industrial Revolution with Professor Nicholas Crafts

Artificial Intelligence and the next Industrial Revolution with Professor Nicholas Crafts

Artificial Intelligence and the next Industrial Revolution with Professor Nicholas Crafts

Artificial Intelligence and the next Industrial Revolution with Professor Nicholas Crafts

Thursday, 11th May 2023
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

0:03

I'm Will Hutton, and you're listening to the Wee

0:06

Society podcast. I'm a journalist,

0:08

a writer, economist, and a fierce

0:10

advocate of the social sciences.

0:13

Now

0:13

more than ever, we need to be listening

0:16

to those with solutions to our world's ills,

0:18

whether that's climate change,

0:20

the cost of living crisis, or something

0:22

more granular, like the low uptake

0:24

of sport in certain communities that could

0:26

damage the health and well-being

0:28

of an entire country. And

0:31

you'll be hearing conversations with top social

0:33

scientists who are addressing just these

0:35

issues in the Wee Society podcast.

0:39

They

0:39

will be bringing us some of the best ideas to shape

0:41

the world we live. As

0:43

the president of the Academy of Social Sciences, I

0:45

know how vital the social sciences are to ensuring

0:48

we are a society of we and

0:50

not an island of I. Social

0:53

scientists are the hidden heroes behind government

0:56

policy, city planning conundrums,

0:58

and top business decisions. By

1:00

engaging with some of the best new ideas, I

1:03

sincerely believe that our world can be

1:05

much improved. I hope

1:07

you enjoy the Wee Society podcast brought

1:09

to you by the Academy of Social Sciences.

1:16

Britain was the first country to industrialize. In 1870,

1:19

we were the richest country in the world. Since

1:22

then, it's been downhill, with the decline

1:24

of anything intensifying over the last 15 years.

1:28

But productivity and investment have stagnated. The Bank

1:30

of England considers our long-run growth rate

1:33

to have sunk below 1% a year. What's

1:36

going on? Can we recover our

1:38

dynamism? Maybe being the first

1:40

to industrialize was not such a great idea.

1:43

It meant we never had to think hard about

1:45

how to build a dynamic economy. What

1:49

lessons are there from our history? With

1:51

me to discuss these issues is Britain's preeminent

1:53

economic historian, Professor Nick Crafts

1:56

at the University of Sussex, after distinguished fellows

1:58

at Oxford, LSE and Bachelor's of Business. Warwick. With

2:01

two books and a hundred referred articles onto

2:03

his belt and now president of the Royal Economic

2:05

Society, the world beats a path

2:07

to his door and we followed suit here

2:10

at his home in Hove. Professor Nick Crafts,

2:13

welcome to the We Society podcast.

2:15

Thank you, I'm delighted to be with you.

2:19

Nick, when we contacted you to

2:21

kind of be interviewed for the We Society podcast

2:23

and you heard the saying We Society, what

2:26

was your first thought at We Society? What do you think

2:28

about? What was your reaction to that kind of concept?

2:31

My reaction to the concept was I'm very

2:34

pleased they want to talk to me, but rather

2:36

surprised. Well I

2:38

hope that when we finish people will not be

2:41

surprised at why we're here. Britain,

2:45

the first to industrialise,

2:47

it all seems so easy and

2:49

it's got more and more difficult

2:51

as the decades have gone by to where we are today.

2:54

There's really a linkage between that. Britain

2:57

was the first country to industrialise

2:59

to go through the Industrial Revolution.

3:02

That wasn't easy actually,

3:05

it was the culmination of many centuries

3:07

of slow development, but

3:10

it was certainly something in which we led the

3:12

world and that

3:14

was a fine accomplishment.

3:17

Although one might say in a

3:20

way it's not a particularly

3:23

sophisticated economy, the

3:25

first motor car,

3:27

the Model T or something like that was a great

3:30

achievement but we wouldn't drive one today.

3:32

Similarly the institutions,

3:36

the

3:37

education system,

3:40

the standard of entrepreneurship,

3:42

probably all those things are things

3:44

which we would say were very good

3:46

for the time but not good enough for

3:49

later on. So the question then

3:51

is whether success

3:53

in the early phase actually

3:56

makes it more difficult or

3:59

whether the subsequently, or

4:01

whether it's simply that adjustment

4:04

was needed, it could have happened, but we didn't

4:06

really do it. But one way or the other,

4:08

you would have needed to adjust. It's

4:11

true that some of the roots

4:14

of institutions, which I

4:16

think did turn out to be problematic

4:19

carriers of history, industrial

4:22

relations being one, a system of

4:24

corporate governance, I think, being another,

4:26

the roots do date back

4:28

to the industrial revolution. And

4:31

I've written certainly things which

4:33

suggest that the early start

4:36

did indeed, in the end, prove to be

4:38

a bit of a handicap.

4:39

Certainly, I mean, working

4:41

on it, as I have been over the last kind of few

4:44

months, I'd be thinking that more and

4:46

more. I mean, it didn't have

4:48

to be the case. The industrial relations

4:50

were quite as adversarial as they got

4:53

to. It didn't have to be the case

4:56

that actually companies were

4:58

governed in the way they were. And that actually

5:01

the supply of external finance

5:04

was as kind of primitive as it was. I mean,

5:07

so that, I mean, when Germany and the United States

5:09

kind of overtook us in the last

5:11

decade of the 19th century, first

5:13

decade of the 20th century, we just didn't know how to respond,

5:16

although we did. I mean, there was the famous

5:18

Macmillan committee, and they

5:20

have very kind of serious recommendations, but somehow

5:23

just kind of washed over the British establishment

5:25

who were kind of convinced all you had to do was free

5:28

trade, small state, laissez-faire,

5:31

adhere to the gold standard, and all would

5:34

be well, but all wasn't well. Well,

5:37

it's certainly true that the Victorians

5:39

were a small state economy.

5:42

It's

5:43

a slight abuse the term, but you might almost

5:45

say laissez-faire. The

5:47

government provided defence,

5:49

law and order, and so on, but

5:52

wasn't terribly ambitious and liked

5:55

to operate on the basis of rules.

5:57

And you've mentioned a couple there. the

6:00

gold standard and the balanced budget were two

6:02

very obvious things. I

6:05

think we did in the interwar period

6:07

start to change really very quickly

6:09

towards a more managed kind

6:12

of economy and indeed that phrase

6:14

can I think be used by the time

6:16

of the 1930s for the development

6:19

strategy that was adopted to

6:21

try and recover from the

6:23

shock of the Depression. I

6:27

think the issue may be and certainly

6:30

in my second book I tried to spell

6:32

this out, that moving

6:34

to a more managed economy took

6:37

away a lot of competition. In

6:40

the absence of competition,

6:42

some of those institutions we

6:44

were just talking about malfunctioned.

6:47

Competition allowed industrial

6:50

relations to deteriorate, possibly

6:53

even encouraged it. Lack

6:55

of competition also was

6:58

a handicap in holding

7:01

management to account. So when

7:03

we think of things which went wrong with the

7:05

British industry, I tend to

7:08

suggest that it's an interaction

7:10

between lack of competition

7:14

by the time that comes about and

7:16

the institutional legacy. So

7:19

I think we can see ourselves changing,

7:22

but the change doesn't work very

7:24

well.

7:25

We're going to spool on to discuss

7:28

today in a minute, but just let's poke about

7:30

a little bit in this

7:33

area that you've raised. I

7:36

mean, 1931 to 1950 is in

7:38

many respects quite an extraordinary

7:41

period of British economy. I mean, the economy

7:43

in 1930 was recognizably

7:46

the late Victorian economy. In 1950,

7:49

I mean, it's

7:52

consumer durables, it's cars, it's

7:55

jet engines, it's radar, it's the

7:58

modernisation was breathtaking.

7:59

And actually,

8:02

it's quite interesting to reflect

8:04

on why that took place. I mean, it wasn't just

8:07

that we had to win a war against Germany. I

8:09

mean, there was a de facto, an

8:11

industrial strategy there, which actually

8:13

the Conservative Party, under Balfour,

8:16

and then Baldwin, you know, really went for. And

8:18

then followed through by the Labour government.

8:21

I mean, is there a lesson? A,

8:23

do you agree with that? And you probably don't. But if you do,

8:25

to the extent that you do agree

8:27

with that, are there lessons

8:29

for us now in 2023? We

8:33

did eventually, in the interwar

8:35

period, start to benefit from

8:37

the technologies of the second

8:39

industrial revolution. You

8:42

do see things like cars and electricity

8:44

making a difference. That's correct.

8:48

But I think insofar as industrial

8:50

policy is concerned, although

8:54

it pretended to be interested

8:56

in what was called rationalisation,

8:59

which might be a word these days we'd replace

9:01

with modernisation or something

9:03

like that, the industrial policy

9:06

of the 1930s is very defensive,

9:09

and it's actually aimed at protecting

9:11

or helping failing industries.

9:15

So it's promoting cartels

9:17

and things like coal and what would

9:20

have happened in cotton had things gone

9:22

a little bit further. It's

9:25

developing a regional policy

9:27

which is trying

9:29

to ameliorate high unemployment,

9:32

but it's certainly not restructuring

9:35

the regions which are struggling as their export

9:37

industries have to confront

9:40

de-globalisation and so

9:42

on. There is a real change

9:45

in the post-war years,

9:48

the Acli government and so on. But

9:51

I think it's hard to see the Acli government

9:53

as having a long-term industrial

9:56

strategy. I think their

9:58

hands are full. with trying

10:00

to deal with the aftermath of World War

10:03

II. The very really

10:05

difficult balance of payments situation

10:08

that was obvious at the time

10:10

really dominated,

10:13

I think, anything to do with long-term

10:16

thinking. They had ideas

10:18

about how to change the

10:21

way the economy ran. So

10:24

most obviously to nationalize

10:27

quite a significant part of the economy.

10:30

We're probably talking about 10 to 12% of the

10:32

economy being in nationalized

10:35

industries. But did they have a strategy

10:38

for what those industries should do? Not

10:40

a convincing one, I don't think.

10:42

Well, I do find it extraordinary

10:45

looking back. I mean, there we were, you know, 780

10:48

to 1860, you

10:51

know, the Great Exhibition of Crystal Palace being one

10:53

component of that, you know, the most dynamic capitalist economy,

10:56

you know, the face of the earth. And

10:58

then 150 years later, you simply

11:00

can't say that. It

11:03

kind of grips with actually, you

11:05

know, what I mean, so

11:08

it was inevitable because, you know, other countries were bound to get

11:10

richer, so there's that. But

11:12

actually, a lot more growth rate of 1% or

11:14

below is

11:16

not great,

11:18

that's where we stand now. Yeah,

11:20

I mean, thinking first of all about

11:23

the period of the Industrial Revolution.

11:25

It was long on growth at 1%, you'd say. Well,

11:28

it's a long period

11:30

of slow acceleration of growth.

11:34

We don't reach a 1% a year growth

11:37

rate for productivity until

11:42

the second quarter of the 19th century. We

11:45

briefly touched 2% in

11:48

that third quarter. But

11:51

we're essentially an

11:54

economy which is capable of growth that

11:56

they wouldn't have dreamt of in the 16th

11:58

century. But it's a

12:01

relatively modest kind of growth

12:03

rate compared with what we saw

12:05

in many countries, including

12:08

our own, in the 20th century. We

12:12

have had periods where we've grown

12:14

quite a lot more rapidly than that

12:17

during the 20th century and

12:19

the peak phase was the

12:22

so-called Golden Age, the

12:25

period between say about 1950 and

12:28

the mid 1970s, labour

12:30

productivity growth in that period is nearly 4%

12:33

a year. We

12:36

were able to grow at a labour

12:39

productivity increase

12:41

of about 2% a year in the 30 or 40 years

12:46

before the financial crisis. That's

12:48

way above anything they could have done through

12:51

most of the industrial revolution. But

12:55

the roof certainly has fallen in

12:57

in the last 15 years or so. And

13:01

if we were or are looking

13:03

at a future of 1% a

13:06

year growth in the future, perhaps

13:10

1% a year productivity growth with the

13:12

labour force not growing a lot, then

13:16

that would be a very disappointing

13:19

outcome. I'm not convinced

13:21

that that is the long term future,

13:24

but I can quite see

13:26

why it's reasonable for

13:28

some people to believe that it will

13:31

be.

13:32

Why? I guess that's the question really.

13:34

I mean, everybody listening to this was saying, well, why? Come

13:36

on, Will. Ask him why. So

13:39

why might we do better? Well,

13:41

why has it gone? Why has it gone pear-shaped? Why

13:44

has it gone pear-shaped? I

13:46

think it's gone pear-shaped for a number

13:49

of reasons. It's not a one reason

13:51

story. The

13:54

financial crisis did do considerable

13:57

damage. It has reduced

13:59

the level. level of productivity that the

14:01

economy can achieve

14:04

compared with not having a financial

14:06

crisis. But it's more than say the United States

14:08

or more than many European economies.

14:11

It's more than most European countries.

14:13

We had a very large financial sector

14:15

prior, but we also

14:18

have had a serious disruption

14:21

to what we might call the process

14:23

of creative destruction and

14:25

so on. So that's a bit of... Just so you know, creative

14:27

destruction is the kind of term that was coined by

14:30

what Schubert, the Austrian economist,

14:32

and the idea is that capitalism

14:34

has to go through phases in which it pulls

14:36

down great companies so

14:39

other ones can grow up. I think I'm

14:41

really not thinking of anything quite as grand

14:43

as that. I'm thinking...

14:45

Well, I wanted to make you feel brand. I'm

14:47

thinking of a vigorous process of entry

14:50

and exit, reallocation of resources,

14:52

rapid exit of the failing

14:54

activity, lots of startups

14:57

of new good activity. Right, lots of startups.

14:59

I mean, it's astonishing that there's a startup... Yeah,

15:02

there's also been a substantial

15:04

number of zombie firms. The

15:06

era of low interest rates allows

15:09

them to survive. If

15:12

you look at measures of entry and exit,

15:15

it's been decreasing over the

15:17

last several years. So

15:19

I'm not saying that's the

15:21

whole story, but I think it's part of the story.

15:24

The second part of this story is

15:27

clearly for me Brexit, in

15:30

the sense that not that we've reached

15:33

the long-term conclusion

15:35

of Brexit, some of the long-term

15:37

effects are still to show up, but

15:39

the actual process of going

15:42

through the leaving creates very

15:45

significant uncertainty, the

15:47

mind investment, and the

15:49

best estimates I've seen in the literature

15:52

say if we've got a 20% productivity

15:55

gap compared with where we might have hoped

15:57

to be, round about 20%.

15:59

on previous form

16:02

then the Brexit part of it might well

16:04

account for five of those 20% something

16:07

of that order. The one that I think matters

16:09

most... Of course if John Redwood was here or Lord

16:11

David Frost they'd be

16:14

saying look you're just not seizing

16:18

the opportunities of Brexit you're just not talking

16:20

it up you're just a Ramoning pessimist you know that's what they would say

16:22

if they were here. Well

16:26

perhaps they should look at the empirical evidence

16:29

and think about the theory

16:29

of how investment works. We

16:33

know that uncertainty is

16:35

a really major handicap

16:38

for an economy in terms of investment.

16:41

We know that not knowing how

16:43

Brexit would pan out was an

16:45

important source of uncertainty.

16:48

I refer you to the survey done by

16:50

the Bank of England by the Stanford Economics

16:53

Team for the Bank of England which

16:55

I think provided a compelling case

16:58

that there's a big productivity cost to

17:00

that. I prefer evidence

17:02

to assertion.

17:06

The third one which I think hasn't

17:08

had as much attention as it might

17:11

and is sort of hidden a bit in the arcane

17:14

the weeds if you like of productivity

17:16

performance is the

17:19

waning of the new economy

17:21

IT, ICT revolution

17:25

which we did pretty well at. We were good

17:27

with that technology by most

17:29

European standards. That

17:31

gave us quite a strong underpinning

17:34

to productivity growth in the 1990s

17:37

around the turn of the century. I

17:40

think it's starting to ever way as

17:42

the financial crisis comes along.

17:45

The arithmetic I've done suggests

17:47

that the slowdown in the

17:50

productivity impact of ICT,

17:53

IT, call it what you will has

17:55

probably knocked about 0.9% a year. of

18:00

our productivity growth rate, might

18:02

account for nearly half of the slowdown.

18:05

Now, if that diagnosis is right,

18:08

then you might say, okay,

18:11

that's the technology we exploited pretty

18:13

well, is there something to

18:15

replace it? If there's something

18:18

to replace it, it might be

18:20

the next phase in a sense

18:23

of that revolution, coming through

18:25

things like AI, artificial

18:28

intelligence, we're excited

18:30

about it at the moment, it's had, I

18:32

suspect, virtually no productivity

18:35

impact. But then these,

18:37

so far, but these big general

18:40

purpose technologies, that's

18:42

the history of them. People

18:44

get excited, they know

18:46

the technology's coming, so to speak,

18:49

well before it has any serious

18:52

economic impact. I'm forecasting

18:55

that for AI, it was

18:57

the story of the Industrial Revolution

18:59

as well.

18:59

The steam engine made essentially

19:02

no difference to British productivity

19:05

before 1830. And

19:07

just to kind of help our listeners, I

19:10

have a general purpose technology, and there's been

19:12

around 30 of them since 10,000 BC, other

19:16

technologies which have a kind

19:19

of transformative impact, not just

19:21

in the sector, but actually

19:24

kind of spillover across

19:26

sectors. So in a state of, railway

19:29

locomotives are great in getting you from A to B, but

19:31

they also kind of open up the world with grain, they

19:34

change warfare, they allow postal

19:36

services to develop, they all have all kinds of spillover. So

19:38

you're saying that, and there's

19:41

quite a sting theory, isn't there? Because we're

19:43

forging our personal knowledge in the 18th century,

19:46

19th century, and eight in the 20th. And

19:48

people are saying there could be a dozen or more

19:50

in the 21st century. And

19:52

the artificial intelligence is one of them, but

19:54

you're saying that may or may not

19:56

be the case. If it is the case, beware,

19:59

because it's...

19:59

does take a while for them to

20:02

get going having their impact. Yeah,

20:04

I'm saying that the

20:06

history suggests that

20:09

there are time lags before the technology

20:11

becomes, whichever this big technology

20:14

is, becomes economically

20:16

important. We can see the

20:18

potential but we have to

20:20

wait before the potential

20:23

is realised.

20:29

Just a quick break in the conversation to tell

20:31

you more about the organisation behind the WeSociety

20:34

podcast. We champion the social sciences

20:37

and highlight the important role academics and

20:39

practitioners have in all sectors of our society,

20:42

whether that's business, health, government,

20:44

education, the list is endless.

20:47

It currently feels like the world's in a state of flux

20:49

as we grapple with the ongoing war in Ukraine,

20:52

the cost of living crisis, spiralling energy

20:54

costs, climate change. The

20:56

social sciences have a vital role to play

20:58

in improving lives and this podcast

21:01

brings you the best ideas to shape the

21:03

way we live. You can find out

21:05

more about the Academy of Social Sciences work, support

21:08

us or read up on our fellows by

21:10

going to the website acss.org.uk.

21:14

That's accss.org.uk.

21:17

You can follow us on Twitter at Akad

21:20

Sock Sciences and tell us

21:22

what we should be covering, who we should be speaking

21:24

to by emailing wesociety

21:27

at acss.org.uk.

21:31

Now back to the conversation.

21:37

So it could be going to a lull in your view. This

21:40

could be the lull before things get

21:42

a great deal better. There could be something of a lull.

21:46

Don't forget how pessimistic people were about productivity

21:49

performance in the United States in

21:51

the 1980s. There

21:53

was Robert Solow saying at the time. Great

21:56

famous professor of economics Robert Solow. We

21:58

can see the computer. everywhere except in

22:01

the productivity statistics. That

22:03

was a great line, wasn't it? 1987, a

22:05

decade later, you could see it in the productivity

22:08

statistics, very, very strong.

22:11

In what ways would artificial intelligence then kind

22:13

of transform productivity? Well, I

22:16

think one really interesting thing is

22:18

it might deliver a new industrial

22:20

revolution if we

22:23

interpret the concept of the industrial

22:26

revolution as the invention

22:28

of a new system of invention.

22:31

If we think of that, the first

22:33

industrial revolution is about, I

22:36

think, measurement, it's about

22:38

becoming more empirical. It's called a

22:40

steam, is that right? No, but

22:43

it isn't a revolution built

22:45

on science, really. They

22:48

have the steam engine, but they don't really understand

22:51

the theory of heat, for argument's

22:53

sake. They have metallurgy

22:55

without the theory

22:57

behind it. A good old fashioned English pragmatist

23:00

is what they would say at the time.

23:01

And empirical observers. They

23:03

systematically build up evidence and

23:05

try and work out what works. By

23:08

the second industrial revolution. Which

23:10

is essentially electricity and chemicals.

23:13

This is

23:15

from, say, about 1870. You

23:19

can see it underway, and it's

23:21

indeed delivering chemicals, electricity,

23:24

the internal combustion engine, and

23:26

so on. That's petrol though, isn't

23:28

it? Because the third industrial revolution has to do with oil and

23:31

carbon. It depends how many you want to choose.

23:33

But if you're following my system

23:36

of invention. Well, I want to follow your system.

23:38

Good. Well, in that case, the

23:40

second industrial revolution is about

23:43

the beginnings of a really important

23:46

role for the industrial

23:48

R&D laboratory. Now

23:50

you need to have people educated

23:52

as scientists and technologists. Now

23:55

you need to have the infrastructure

23:58

at, say, the tertiary education. level

24:01

to deliver enough of those people.

24:04

That's where we start falling behind

24:07

the Americans and the Germans. We're not

24:09

good at making that adjustment

24:12

or adaptation. The

24:14

third Industrial Revolution arguably

24:17

is the ICT one and

24:19

ICT starts to deliver

24:22

new ways of doing research

24:24

amongst other things and software

24:27

makes a massive difference

24:29

to the system of invention. AI

24:33

is another potential system

24:36

of invention. One

24:38

of my economic historian colleagues

24:41

said amongst other things AI

24:43

might be the best researcher system

24:45

the world has ever had. If

24:48

you're looking for needles in haystacks,

24:51

smaller needles and bigger haystacks

24:53

is definitely available now. That's

24:55

a very simple way of looking at it because I always assumed my

24:58

topology, what my topology,

24:59

the topology that I have in my head I think

25:02

in other people's heads as well. First Industrial

25:04

Revolution, steam, coal,

25:07

second Industrial Revolution, chemicals, electricity,

25:10

third Industrial Revolution, oil,

25:12

petrol, fourth Industrial Revolution, data,

25:15

which encompasses both ICT and

25:18

AI. But you're saying no

25:20

no Will, that's not the way to think about it.

25:23

The only thing about it is to kind of separate out ICT

25:25

and AI. I would probably separate

25:28

them out but the more important thing

25:30

I'm saying is that Industrial

25:33

Revolutions are about how

25:35

technological progress comes about.

25:38

We can itemize some of the technologies

25:40

they give rise to.

25:42

But the difference in general purpose

25:44

technologies between if you want

25:47

to roll together data and AI,

25:49

I'll go with that if you like, that

25:52

is something which is adding

25:55

to the process of invention. The

25:57

steam engine is jolly good at carrying.

26:00

people pumping water

26:02

out of mines, powering

26:04

tech star factories, but it doesn't

26:08

help you find more knowledge

26:10

across the piece, whereas data

26:13

and AI do.

26:15

Give us a sense, just

26:17

a kind of future scope for a minute, give us

26:20

a kind of window into the Nick Crafts

26:22

mind. I mean, 10, 20 years time, what

26:24

kinds of technology

26:27

do you think will be underpinning

26:29

our economy? Where will the jobs be?

26:32

What can we do to make sure we

26:34

get our fair share of those, or

26:36

have more than our fair share? I mean, what

26:39

can we do as a country to kind

26:41

of, you know, be in there fighting for the

26:44

frontiers of this and pulling

26:45

great companies out of it? All the rest. Come

26:48

on, Will, I'm an economic historian, so I'm

26:50

only good at looking backwards.

26:54

Occasionally, come on,

26:56

as you wonder, how do you work to have a cup of

26:58

tea? I think the semi-serious

27:00

answer to your question is,

27:03

I don't know. And that's quite

27:05

an important thing to know that you don't

27:07

know. If

27:08

you don't exactly know which of the

27:10

jobs which will disappear and the new

27:13

ones come along, which we've perhaps not dreamt

27:15

of some of them, then what

27:18

you need to have is a system

27:20

which can adapt and be flexible

27:23

when the time comes. That

27:25

tells you, I think, something about how

27:28

you want to educate people. It

27:30

tells you something about how

27:33

you might handle the process of

27:35

creative destruction, to go back

27:37

to that phrase again. It seems

27:41

to me you've got to persuade people

27:43

to be willing to accept that

27:46

creative destruction is part

27:48

of a successful capitalist economy,

27:51

in which case you've got to deal

27:54

with issues to do with what happens to them when

27:56

they do lose their job. to

28:00

deal with that in a way which offers them

28:02

true social insurance and

28:05

an active labour market policy to

28:08

go with it to help

28:10

them into redeployment.

28:13

The key thing making success of

28:15

some transformative technology

28:18

is that you don't end up with the

28:20

displaced workers unemployed,

28:23

you have them redeployed.

28:26

And that is,

28:29

I think, how we should position ourselves

28:32

for a future we can't know

28:35

in terms of what exactly it will be that

28:37

comes along and exactly what

28:39

disappears. At this point

28:41

you've made about distinguishing

28:44

between jobs and worker.

28:47

I hear you talk, I see

28:49

myself, the rise of

28:51

late 19th century trade unionism and early 20th century

28:53

trade unionism. They

28:56

wanted to protect workers

28:58

obviously, but actually because

29:00

unions are people

29:02

who hold jobs,

29:04

it always ended up being job protection rather than worker

29:06

protection. So that's a

29:09

long shadow actually, isn't it? It's very deep

29:12

in our culture, I think. I think it

29:14

is. Now look, let's write this off,

29:16

let's pull this together, because you've

29:18

been talking here for half an hour and

29:20

began this asking, can we recover our

29:23

dynamism? Can we do better

29:25

than the last 15 years? Because

29:28

it's a very kind of doleful

29:31

picture, I mean not

29:32

great. And lots of young people

29:34

are kind of worrying about

29:36

getting married or whether they should leave the country.

29:38

I mean it seems to be going nowhere.

29:40

But on the other hand, there's reservoirs

29:43

of possibility. Where are you on

29:45

this? Are you an optimist?

29:48

Or is relative decline

29:50

going to continue? You

29:53

could be an optimist in terms of thinking that

29:55

the productivity growth rate might improve

29:58

or will improve.

29:59

without necessarily thinking that

30:02

that would end relative economic decline.

30:05

Relative economic decline is about having

30:08

productivity growth rates which are slower,

30:11

lower than your peer

30:13

group, whoever it is you're comparing

30:15

your progress with. I

30:18

am optimistic because I do think

30:20

there is scope for another

30:24

resurgence of technological

30:26

progress in the economy. But essentially

30:29

you're saying

30:29

there are things to be done, I've itemized

30:32

them. There's a

30:35

lot of new technology going to be around the

30:37

rest of the world which we will import and I hope

30:39

we'll do well with

30:42

it. Whether we'll do better than others

30:45

is an open question. Yeah, that

30:47

sums it up very nicely.

30:49

Nick Krasst, thank you very much. Thank

30:51

you very much for fascinating kind of 40

30:54

minutes in which we have looked at

30:56

the Industrial Revolution in which she reminded

30:58

us that it was slow burn and

31:00

that the growth rate wasn't very fast.

31:03

It was just happened year after year

31:05

after year which hadn't happened ever

31:07

before then. You've discussed

31:10

the second and third Industrial Revolutions

31:12

and said that, described how we

31:15

lack the institutions to exploit

31:18

them well

31:19

and thus fallen behind.

31:22

You told us that the

31:24

productivity gap that we currently have

31:27

is partly about Brexit, partly

31:30

because we had an oversized financial

31:32

services sector which was hit

31:34

by the financial crisis and partly

31:36

because we were doing well

31:39

with information communication technology

31:42

that seems to have tailed away. But it's

31:44

an open question whether we'll manage to kind of recover

31:47

our place in the League of Nations but we might do

31:49

well enough to be a prosperous country and a happy

31:51

country. So that's the thought to end on. Thank

31:55

you very much Nick, thank you. Thank you.

31:59

Thank you so much for joining in the

32:02

conversation. The We Society

32:04

is brought to you by the Academy of Social Sciences,

32:07

acss.org.uk. I'm

32:10

Will Hutton, the producer is Emily

32:12

Finch, and it's a Whistledown production.

32:15

If you haven't already, please subscribe to the

32:17

podcast, leave a comment, share with your

32:19

colleagues and friends, or send us an email

32:22

and tell us what we should be asking and

32:24

who we should talk to.

Rate

Join Podchaser to...

  • Rate podcasts and episodes
  • Follow podcasts and creators
  • Create podcast and episode lists
  • & much more

Episode Tags

Do you host or manage this podcast?
Claim and edit this page to your liking.
,

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features