Podchaser Logo
Home
Cantero v. Bank of America, N.A.

Cantero v. Bank of America, N.A.

Released Tuesday, 27th February 2024
Good episode? Give it some love!
Cantero v. Bank of America, N.A.

Cantero v. Bank of America, N.A.

Cantero v. Bank of America, N.A.

Cantero v. Bank of America, N.A.

Tuesday, 27th February 2024
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

0:00

We'll hear argument next in Case 22529, Kentaro v. Bank of

0:02

America. Mr. Taylor. Mr.

0:06

Chief Justice, and may it please the Court, Section

0:09

25B pre-empts a State consumer

0:11

financial law only if, as

0:14

relevant here, it prevents or significantly

0:16

interferes with the exercise of a

0:19

national bank's powers. Bank

0:21

of America argues, and the Second

0:23

Circuit held, that this statute pre-empts

0:25

any law that controls or otherwise

0:27

hinders the exercise of a national

0:29

bank's powers, regardless of

0:31

whether the law has any significant

0:33

effect on such powers. This

0:36

test conflicts with the statute for

0:38

four reasons. First, Section

0:41

25B's definition of State consumer financial

0:43

law is incompatible with a control

0:45

test because it would require that

0:48

every such law be preempted, nullifying

0:50

the statute, and erecting the very

0:53

field-preemption regime that the statute bids.

0:56

Bank of America's only retort is

0:58

to concede that State fair lending laws

1:00

aren't categorically preempted, a concession

1:03

it doesn't explain, and that

1:05

disproves its own test. Second,

1:08

the control test ignores Section 25B's

1:10

express codification of Barnett banks

1:13

prevents or significantly interferes with standard,

1:15

and in particular the word significantly,

1:17

which Bank of America reads out

1:19

of the statute. Third, a

1:22

control test can't be squared with

1:24

Section 25B's provisions for OCC

1:26

preemption determinations, which

1:28

must assess the impact of a State

1:30

law and be based on substantial evidence.

1:32

These requirements would make no sense if

1:35

a control test were the law. Finally,

1:37

and perhaps most fundamentally, adopting

1:39

a control test would require

1:41

reading virtually all of Section

1:44

25B to have no real-world

1:46

effect. With no plausible

1:48

textual argument, Bank of America turns

1:50

to policy claiming that its test

1:52

is needed to avoid mayhem, but

1:55

Congress disagreed, and Section 25B has

1:57

a solution to this concern. SEC

2:00

can make the preemption determinations contemplated by

2:02

the statute, that it has thus far

2:04

failed to respect the statute's commands, grants

2:07

no license to this court to do

2:09

the same. I welcome the court's questions.

2:12

I'd be interested in you giving

2:15

us your explanation as

2:18

to how Barnett

2:20

Bank gives us

2:22

guidance as to how

2:24

to interpret, prevent, or significantly interfere.

2:27

Sure, Justice Thomas. So Barnett

2:29

Bank uses the prevents

2:32

or significantly interferes with standard as a

2:34

kind of distillation of the rule that

2:36

emerges from this court's cases. Now of

2:38

course the conflict that was issued in

2:40

Barnett Bank was a stark conflict. It

2:42

involved a state statute that said banks

2:45

may not do X and a federal statute

2:47

that said national banks may do X and

2:49

this court was able to resolve that as

2:52

a clear conflict. But it didn't give

2:54

much guidance itself in terms of what

2:56

significant interferes with means but

2:58

it did articulate that as the standard

3:00

that emerges from this court's cases and

3:02

the first case that it cited was

3:04

this court's decision in Anderson and Anderson

3:06

involved a Kentucky cheat law and

3:09

the court in that case there was a

3:11

preemption challenge that was brought to that statute

3:13

by the national bank and the court in

3:15

that case said that's not a discriminatory statute.

3:17

It was the first question the court asked.

3:19

It doesn't conflict with any statutory text and

3:21

so we examine the law's practical effect

3:23

and in examining the law's practical effect

3:25

it distinguished a prior decision from this

3:27

court that reached the opposite outcome and

3:29

the only way to explain that pair

3:31

of cases is that the court examines the

3:34

practical effect. And so I think the

3:36

one thing that we know of the

3:38

prevents or significantly interferes with standard and

3:40

what it means is that it requires

3:42

an examination at a minimum of

3:44

the practical effect of the statute and

3:47

that's clear from the ordinary meaning of

3:49

the phrase and it's confirmed by the

3:51

surrounding text in section 25B including the

3:54

provision that requires that the OCC examine

3:56

the law's impact based on substantial evidence

3:58

and periodically review. Exactly does

4:00

it mean to examine the practical effect? Why

4:04

don't you talk about this law and

4:06

say how an analysis of that kind

4:08

would work with respect to this law

4:10

and then maybe say anything more general

4:12

you want because it seems to provide

4:15

no guidance at all to courts as

4:17

to what they have to do. I

4:19

will answer that question directly, but I will say

4:22

that because of the way that Bank of America

4:24

has argued the case and the way that the

4:26

Second Circuit decided the case, the only question that

4:28

this Court has to confront is whether the control

4:30

test is codified as part of Section

4:32

25B or whether instead courts must look

4:34

to the practical effect of the law.

4:37

I appreciate that, but one thing that

4:39

we should think about at least in

4:41

considering whether the practical effect test that

4:43

you are suggesting is the one that

4:46

is codified and is the appropriate one

4:48

is what would that mean? What

4:51

would it look like? Then

4:53

we can consider whether that is

4:56

what Congress had in mind.

4:58

It might look like the

5:01

showing that the National Bank made in Franklin National

5:03

Bank, for example, and I would recommend that you

5:05

look at the trial court decision in that case.

5:07

That case involved a federal statute

5:09

that granted to National Bank the authority to

5:12

accept savings deposits. New York had

5:15

a statute that didn't prohibit National

5:17

Banks from accepting savings deposits,

5:20

but disabled them from using the word savings

5:22

in their business operation

5:24

and in their advertisements or

5:27

any equivalent thereof and reserved

5:30

to certain state institutions the

5:32

privilege to use that word. What

5:35

the National Bank said in that case,

5:37

it identified real world evidence showing the

5:39

tremendous extent to which that law served

5:42

as an obstacle to attempting

5:44

to accept savings

5:47

deposits and its business operations. The

5:50

trial court in that case found what is

5:52

effectively significant interference. By the time that case

5:55

got to this court, this court,

5:57

although it resolved the question before

6:00

against statutory construction grounds emphasizing

6:02

the statute, the federal statute's use of

6:04

the word savings, I think it had

6:06

confidence based on the record before it

6:09

that that word mattered

6:11

in the real world. And if

6:13

that standard had been used here,

6:15

what would that have meant? What

6:18

evidence would the parties have put on

6:20

and how would the court have addressed

6:22

the issue? So the legal question

6:24

would be whether there's significant interference and we think

6:26

that looks to the practical effect and Bank of

6:28

America would have to identify what the practical effect

6:31

is. I think it would be particularly easy

6:33

for it to do so here because we have a statute that's

6:35

been on the books for 50 years. State

6:37

banks have been complying with it. Most

6:39

federal banks, it's my understanding, have been

6:41

complying with it and indeed there was

6:43

a preemption challenge that was immediately brought

6:45

and it failed and presumably national banks

6:47

were complying with it after that. And

6:49

so they could look at the data

6:51

showing the extent to which this minimum

6:53

interest requirement has caused banks to not

6:56

offer mortgage escrow services, which would

6:58

be the relevant power to consumers.

7:03

And I think it would just be a question of degree

7:05

at that point and I would concede that it's not a

7:07

bright line test. Congress didn't want a

7:09

bright line test. It had before

7:12

it various proposals that would have been

7:14

a bright line test including field preemption,

7:16

that's administrable, but we know that Congress

7:18

didn't want that. And on the other

7:20

hand, the Department of the Treasury submitted

7:22

a proposal that would have made preemption

7:24

determinations turn entirely on whether the law

7:26

is discriminatory. That's also administrable, but

7:28

in the judgment of Congress that didn't go

7:31

far enough to provide protection to the bank. Banks

7:34

and Congress wanted to give banks as

7:36

an accommodation the opportunity in a case-by-case

7:38

basis to show that there's a significant

7:40

interference. And that's the scheme that... I'm

7:43

going to ask about Franklin because I

7:45

think Franklin's a critical case here because

7:47

it's identified in Barnett, identified in Waters.

7:52

And in figuring out, as Justice Kagan

7:54

and Justice Thomas says, what significantly interferes

7:56

means, I think one way to do is

7:59

look at... look at the

8:01

precedent applying it. So Barnett,

8:03

you look at that first, but Barnett

8:05

really rests heavily on Franklin. We

8:07

know Franklin is correctly decided

8:10

under the statute. Do you agree with that?

8:12

Agree with that entirely. Okay. So then the

8:14

question, I think, one way to look at

8:16

it, you tell me why this is wrong,

8:18

is does this kind of state

8:20

law at issue here significantly

8:22

interfere more than

8:24

the law did in Franklin? Is that a good way

8:27

to look at it? You could put it

8:29

that way, yes. Okay. And doesn't

8:31

a law that interferes with

8:33

the pricing of the

8:35

product, almost by

8:37

definition, interfere more with

8:40

the operations of the bank than

8:42

something that affects advertising? I

8:44

don't think so, Justice Cavanaugh. The question

8:47

isn't whether it would

8:49

cost money to the bank to comply with the

8:51

statute. The question rather... Let

8:54

me stop you right there. Why

8:56

not? That sounds like significant interference

8:58

when it's affecting how much it's

9:00

almost putting a tax on

9:03

the bank

9:05

to sell the product,

9:07

which strikes me as a much more

9:09

significant interference than simply saying

9:12

you can't use the word savings

9:14

in your advertising, which was

9:16

the issue in Franklin. Well,

9:18

if the test for preemption turned entirely

9:20

on compliance costs, then a whole bunch

9:22

of generally applicable laws that my friend

9:24

on the other side concedes are

9:27

not preempted would nevertheless be preempted if

9:29

it costs money to the bank to comply with

9:31

those. So I don't think compliance costs alone are

9:33

enough. I think what you need instead is what

9:35

this court said in Barnett Bank, which is it's

9:37

not enough that there just be significant interference with

9:41

profits. The question

9:43

is whether there's a significant interference with a

9:45

power that Congress explicitly granted. So the focus

9:48

is on what... But how did that happen

9:50

in Franklin? Franklin, they

9:52

could do... the bank could do everything

9:54

that it previously did. It just couldn't

9:57

use the word savings in its advertisement,

9:59

which didn't matter. prevented from exercising its

10:02

power. That's right, but as I was explaining to Justice

10:04

Kagan earlier, if you take a look at the record

10:06

in that case, that case shows that

10:08

a factual showing can be made and was

10:10

made in that case, and I would commend

10:12

the trial court's decision there because I think

10:15

it's illuminating for this question. And

10:17

everyone in the case seemed to understand, coming on the

10:19

heels of Anderson, that there was gonna be some kind

10:21

of a practical showing. And this court

10:23

noted the large record showing the real world consequences

10:25

of the law in its opinion. And

10:28

there was all kinds of, there was testimony, there

10:31

was consumer polling, there was law sales, there

10:33

was significant amount of data showing the degree

10:35

to which this prohibition had

10:37

a real world effect. Isn't

10:40

it true that the New York Court of

10:42

Appeals, when it upheld the law, said

10:45

that it had no, quote, seriously

10:48

harmful effects on national banks? That

10:51

may have been what it said,

10:53

but if you look at the trial court's finding

10:55

in the case, the trial court found that based

10:57

on the evidence that I was discussing with Justice

10:59

Kagan on the law,

11:01

quote, certainly restricts national banks tremendously in

11:03

obtaining savings deposits. And that's effectively a

11:05

finding of significant interference. I mean, the

11:08

law said they couldn't use savings in

11:10

their advertising, but they could use a

11:14

comparable phrase like special

11:16

interest account. And

11:19

so if any

11:21

interference that's greater than the interference

11:23

there is

11:25

enough, that wouldn't

11:29

be, I don't see how you can win

11:31

under that. Two responses, Justice Alito. If

11:34

you look at the testimony in

11:36

that case, it was clear

11:38

that consumers had no idea what interest

11:40

bearing account meant. I mean, the word

11:42

savings actually mattered to their purchasing decisions,

11:44

and it had a real world effect.

11:46

And that was a law that was

11:49

discriminatory and put the national banks at

11:51

a serious competitive disadvantage, vis-a-vis state banks.

11:53

And of course, under this statute, a

11:55

discriminatory law would be preempted for

11:59

independent reasons. And so the way

12:01

that this statute is designed is that non-discrimination

12:03

is the most important

12:06

principle that runs through the statute.

12:08

And if a law is non-discriminatory,

12:10

then I think we can assume

12:12

that the hostility that states

12:14

have traditionally shown to national banks are not

12:16

gonna be reflected in their laws because we're

12:18

only gonna be talking about laws that involve

12:20

restrictions that states are willing to impose on

12:22

their own banks and they're not gonna devour

12:24

their own. And so-

12:26

Do you think that the significant interference test

12:29

should be applied on a bank by bank

12:31

basis or on an industry basis? No, it's

12:33

not bank by bank. That's not how it

12:36

works. Now, if you look at the statute,

12:38

it's clear that when the OCC makes preemption

12:40

determinations, think it does so on a law

12:42

by law basis, not a bank by bank

12:44

basis. And even there in consultation with the

12:47

CFPB, it can make preemption determinations. It'll be

12:49

on that law and reach substantively equivalent laws.

12:51

And so- Is that a question of, a

12:54

pure question of law? Is it a

12:56

mixed question? Is it a question of fact? The

13:00

ultimate preemption determination-

13:02

Now, the question of whether it significantly

13:04

interferes, is that a question of fact?

13:06

It's a legal question for a court.

13:09

But it, because it takes account

13:11

of the practical effects of the law, you

13:13

have to know what those effects are. And

13:15

it's gonna be, if the OCC hasn't identified

13:17

the effects, then it's gonna

13:19

be incumbent on the bank if there's no

13:21

statute on point and we're talking about a

13:23

non-discriminatory law to explain what those

13:25

effects are. And then the fight is not gonna

13:27

be about necessarily the effects of the law, but

13:29

about whether that rises to the level of significant-

13:33

Well, the burden would be on the plaintiff

13:35

challenging it, wouldn't it? Well,

13:38

this is, I mean, if the plaintiff is a national

13:41

bank challenging the law, then yes, the burden would be

13:43

on the national bank. Conversely, if

13:45

the bird, as

13:47

in this case, preemption

13:50

is raised as an affirmative defense, then the burden

13:52

would still be on the national bank. How

13:55

do you envision this trial taking place?

13:57

So a district judge, let's

13:59

say- in the Southern District of

14:01

New York, Eastern District of New

14:03

York, wherever, is going to have

14:06

a trial to determine the

14:08

effect of this on all national

14:10

banks up reading

14:12

in New York. And

14:16

is that going to involve extensive

14:19

discovery? Would it

14:21

involve testimony by experts?

14:25

If the court makes a

14:27

decision, what standard of review is

14:29

going to be applied

14:33

by the Second Circuit? So

14:35

we don't think that there are going to be a

14:38

bunch of mini trials to determine

14:40

the preemption question. And I'll just say as a

14:42

predicate to my response, Justice Alito, I think it's

14:44

fairly unlikely that a lot of the hypothetical laws

14:46

that you see at the back of the Red

14:48

Brief will ever come to pass because of the

14:51

nondiscrimination principle that I was talking about. Well, I

14:53

understand that. But you say

14:55

in your brief, either in your opening brief or

14:57

your reply brief, I

14:59

think it's in your reply brief, you say this

15:02

may not even require any evidence. This

15:05

question could be decided without evidence.

15:08

Really? Well, it's a factual

15:10

question. At least it's a heavily factual question. How's

15:12

it going to be decided without evidence? Well, you'd

15:15

have to know what the effects are. So that

15:17

would require some evidence

15:19

in the typical case. But if it's clear

15:21

from the face of the statute, if it's

15:23

just obviously punitive and it's past the point

15:25

of reasonable people being able to disagree as

15:27

to whether there's significant interference,

15:29

then I think that could be decided as a

15:31

matter of economic logic, which is consistent with what

15:34

this Court has done in other... The

15:36

matter of economic logic? There's

15:39

economic logic that tells you whether

15:41

something substantially affects the

15:44

operation of a commercial enterprise?

15:47

If you

15:49

looked at page 15 of our

15:51

reply brief, we identify some cases

15:53

involving preemption regimes that affect entire

15:55

industries, airline industry, motor

15:58

care industry, you know, ERISA, you name it. and

16:00

prescription drugs, and it is

16:02

often the case in those

16:04

contexts that there is a

16:07

factual showing that

16:10

needs to be made, and sometimes this

16:12

court, included in the Morales decision, for

16:14

example, has resolved the preemption question, even

16:17

though it turns on significant effect based on

16:19

economic logic. Now, I think it would be

16:22

difficult to do that for the ordinary case,

16:24

because we can presume that states aren't going

16:26

to inflict, obviously, punitive

16:29

restrictions on their own banks, and so,

16:31

and this law would be an example

16:33

of that, but if a state were crazy enough to

16:35

do that. I don't

16:38

think Franklin did this, what you're

16:40

talking about, and

16:42

the Supreme Court in Franklin. No,

16:45

that's right. And Franklin, I think, is kind

16:47

of our North Star here, at least

16:49

as I've unpacked the

16:51

case. But I think Franklin, you

16:53

could either read it as being a case about

16:55

significant interference based on the record, as I pointed

16:57

out, or I think what this court said is

16:59

it just engaged in statutory interpretation. It said,

17:02

we've got a federal statute that says national

17:05

banks make sense savings deposits, and the

17:07

word savings matters, it's the label that

17:09

Congress used for these accounts, and states

17:11

can't pose a serious practical

17:14

impediment to that by saying you can't use

17:16

that same label. And so, that case could

17:18

be understood on statutory construction grounds based on

17:20

the express statutory power that was granted by

17:23

the statute, and we have nothing like that

17:25

here. Thank you, counsel. Justice Thomas, any further?

17:28

Justice Alito. Well, the way you just described

17:30

Franklin sounds, you know, awful lot like what

17:32

the Second Circuit did here. No,

17:36

they said that the

17:38

national bank has a certain power, and

17:42

the state conditions

17:44

the exercise of

17:47

that national power on compliance with the

17:49

state requirement, and that's enough to prove

17:52

that there's preemption. That's what I just understood you

17:54

to say. Justice

17:56

Alito, my understanding was-

17:58

I must have, maybe I- I misunderstood

18:00

you. So maybe I was simply trying

18:03

to clarify that Franklin National Bank could

18:05

be understood based on specific statutory text

18:07

that is nothing like any statutory text

18:09

that Bank of America has identified. I

18:11

thought you were saying, and again correct

18:14

me if I misunderstood you, but it's

18:16

important to my thinking about this, that

18:19

the issue that Franklin Bank can

18:21

be understood as deciding this issue

18:23

without examining the empirical question of

18:26

the extent to which there

18:29

was an impact on the operation of

18:31

the bank. I thought that's what you said. I

18:33

guess I would put a little bit differently then,

18:35

Justice Alito. I think that the Court, in its

18:37

opinion, it notes the

18:39

record that had been amassed on this

18:41

question as to the practical consequences of

18:43

the law, and I think that record

18:45

gave it some comfort and confirmed why

18:47

it was significant that Congress would have

18:50

used the statutory term savings, but ultimately

18:52

its opinion rests on a statutory

18:54

analysis of the word savings

18:56

and a specific statutory interpretation

18:58

that would present a

19:01

sort of – you could think of it as

19:03

being a conflict in that sense, and it's nothing

19:05

like the kind of conflict that we have here.

19:07

All right. Thank you. Thank you.

19:10

Justice Sun-Lior. The government asks us

19:12

to vacate and remand and let the Second

19:14

Circuit apply whatever we say is the correct

19:16

test. You're asking us to reverse.

19:20

What's the difference and why don't we

19:22

do what the U.S. is recommending? We

19:25

would be happy with the vacator, and I

19:27

think it's the most modest way for this Court to decide

19:30

the question before it. The reason why we're

19:32

asking for reversal is we think that as

19:35

long as there's a requirement that the

19:37

practical effect of the law be examined,

19:39

that Bank of America has failed to

19:41

make that showing, and since

19:44

it's failed to make that showing, then its motion

19:46

to dismiss should be denied, and it can make

19:48

the showing at a later stage of litigation or

19:50

put in some declarations or something and seek summary

19:53

judgment if it thinks it can meet the statutory

19:56

statute. I don't know whether or not that's right.

19:58

I mean, if statute doesn't speak in terms of practical – It

20:01

talks about preventing or significantly

20:03

interfering with

20:05

the exercise of a national bank

20:07

power. So I do

20:09

think that there is a difference

20:12

between practical effect and that language. Well,

20:14

I think that language in ordinarily parlance

20:16

could only be understood to say that

20:18

to be able to answer that question,

20:20

you've got to know what the practical

20:22

effect of the law is. And

20:25

you don't have to necessarily know what the degree

20:27

is. I mean, that people can disagree about that.

20:29

But at a minimum, you've got to

20:32

take some account of what the practical effect

20:34

is. And once you recognize that... So you're... At

20:37

what point you mentioned

20:40

earlier that the OCC could

20:43

decide some of these prevention issues?

20:46

Because under your take of this law

20:48

now, that

20:51

national banks, all state laws

20:53

would apparently apply to national

20:55

banks, unless and until

20:57

those banks obtain final judgments

20:59

of preemption state by state,

21:01

correct? I think

21:04

that is correct. Now, the

21:06

other side's saying that's an

21:08

alarming unpredictability. And some of

21:10

my colleagues are concerned about

21:13

that. Why don't you address that

21:15

straight on? But you mentioned

21:17

in your opening that you thought the OCC could

21:19

do it. Well, the OCC has done it here.

21:22

There's a question of whether they've applied the

21:24

right standard in doing it. Yeah. But

21:27

they have done it. Well,

21:30

the statute, they haven't done it consistent with

21:32

the procedures set up by the statute. And

21:34

I don't even think Bank of America is

21:36

arguing they've done it consistent with the procedures

21:38

set up by the statute. But if... I

21:41

think it would be appropriate for a court on remand

21:43

to look at what the OCC has said about the

21:46

effect of this law. You'll

21:48

find that there's not much there in either the

21:50

2011 rulemaking or the 2004 rulemaking

21:52

or in the amicus brief that the OCC submitted

21:55

below. But we think that it

21:57

would be appropriate for a court to consider that as part

21:59

of the analysis. But I would

22:01

also just, I appreciate the

22:03

other side's concern about the practical

22:05

consequences of reading

22:09

the statute for what it says. And I would

22:11

just say a couple of things. One is that

22:13

I think you could, in your opinion, remind

22:16

lower courts that this is not the only

22:18

path to preemption. There's the requirement that

22:20

the law be non-discriminatory, and there's still the

22:23

requirement that it not pose a square conflict

22:25

of the sort that it was an issue

22:27

in Barnett Bank, which covers the significant

22:32

interference. Point to

22:34

Anderson and Franklin as we've been discussing. But the

22:36

OCC has a role to play there too. And

22:38

the OCC does have expertise, and to the extent

22:40

that it thinks a particular state law is

22:43

very troubling and poses a significant interference, it

22:45

can endeavor to explain why in a rulemaking

22:47

consistent with the statute, and courts can look

22:49

at that, and to the extent that it's

22:51

persuasive, they can defer to it, and that

22:53

gives the banks the kind of predictability

22:57

that they crave. Whether we like

22:59

the case-by-case approach, the

23:02

statute requires it. I think I would

23:04

have expected you to say that to someone.

23:08

We certainly think that you should read the statute and apply it

23:10

as written. Mrs.

23:12

Kagan. It could be an

23:14

example of a non-discriminatory state

23:16

law that would be

23:19

preempted as a significant interference.

23:21

I don't know that I can answer that question in

23:23

the abstract, but I mean, well, I guess I can.

23:26

But the OCC would be an example. So

23:28

even if that's non-discriminatory, it poses a clear

23:30

conflict because it's a total conflict. So

23:33

you separated that out as a case that poses

23:35

a clear conflict. What is the category of that

23:37

case? Are there cases that

23:39

fall in other categories that might pass

23:42

the significant interference test? I

23:44

guess what I'm asking about is,

23:47

you say of Bank America's test that

23:49

it would preempt everything, but

23:51

one could say about your test that

23:53

it would preempt basically nothing, as long

23:56

as a statute was indeed

23:58

non-discriminatory. And indeed, that

24:00

was the Treasury Department's proposal

24:03

that preemption would just turn on whether a

24:06

state law was discriminatory. And if it wasn't discriminatory,

24:08

then it wouldn't be preempted. And we know Congress

24:10

didn't select that regime. So it's got to do

24:13

some work beyond non-discrimination. I'd just bring that up

24:15

to point out that we know that ease of

24:17

administration wasn't top of mind. Yeah, so what's the

24:19

work? Give me some statutes. So the

24:21

statute says prevents or significantly interferes with. We think

24:23

the word prevents is how you take care of

24:26

a case like Barnett Bank. It just, if it's

24:28

a square conflict, it prevents the exercise of the

24:30

power granted by Congress. That can be resolved just

24:33

with legal briefing. But if

24:35

you're at the point of substantial or

24:37

significant interference, rather, that's a question of

24:39

degree. And it's very difficult to answer

24:41

that on the abstract. I'd want to know whether

24:44

there's a federal, what the federal statutory scheme,

24:46

what the regulatory scheme is, what the

24:48

OCC has said about it, what the practical

24:50

on the ground impact is. And it's

24:52

ultimately a judgment call. It's a question

24:54

of degree. And I think you

24:57

might know a lot about state bank and

24:59

statutes. Is there any state banking statute out

25:01

there that you think presents a hard question?

25:05

Nothing comes immediately to mind.

25:09

But I think you could imagine if a state

25:11

were to say, you can't have

25:13

mortgage escrow accounts. Well, of course, that would,

25:15

as applied to the covered accounts, you

25:18

would pose a square conflict with the

25:20

federal statute. But if you totally disabled

25:22

states, national banks, from being able to

25:24

exercise a particular power, that's

25:28

a prevents case. But the question of significant

25:30

interference is necessarily one of degree. And

25:32

it's tough to know in the abstract

25:35

exactly when it would be satisfied. I need to know

25:38

what the actual on the

25:40

ground impact is and the

25:42

extent to which that significantly interfered

25:44

with the national banks exercises the particular

25:47

power issue in the case is confirmed

25:49

by Congress. Justice Gorsuch? Justice

25:51

Cameron? I think you said it's a judgment

25:53

call on a matter of degree. Would a

25:56

10% state

25:58

law, would that be significant interference? So

26:00

if it's non-discriminatory, I'm assuming for the purpose

26:02

of the hypothetical it would be non-discriminatory, although

26:04

I think requiring that it be non-discriminatory makes

26:06

it particularly unlikely that a state would ever

26:08

do something like that. But indulging the hypothetical,

26:11

then it would be exactly where we are

26:13

now. It's a question of significant interference and

26:15

it would be a question of degree. Judgment

26:17

call for whom? I guess for us, for the

26:19

nine of us to just decide? Well the question

26:22

as to what significant interference means is

26:25

ultimately a legal question and it turns

26:27

on what the actual practical on the

26:29

ground impact is and if the bank in

26:31

that scenario could say, look. With the judgment call,

26:33

who's the, we're making the judgment call or the

26:35

court's view? Ultimately it would be a legal question

26:37

and Justice Lidl, you asked earlier about the standard

26:39

of review. That would be de novo, I mean

26:41

to the extent that it rested on factual findings,

26:43

you know, that would be a different standard. But

26:45

the ultimate legal question of significant interference is for

26:47

a court and ultimately, you know, subject to review

26:49

by this court. And I guess I'm going to

26:51

go back to Franklin then and say, well, we're

26:53

not just doing this, we're not totally at sea

26:56

when we have to do this under your approach.

26:59

Franklin says some limits on

27:01

your advertising and how you describe

27:03

your product, that is significant

27:05

interference. And you agree that that's correct?

27:09

I think that's a way to understand that case

27:11

and so if you wanted to give guidance to

27:13

lower courts, you could use Franklin National Bank as

27:15

an example just as the Barnet Bank court did

27:17

in its opinion. And I guess here, I mean,

27:20

maybe this is for remander for us, but telling

27:23

a bank not how you

27:25

describe your product and your advertising, but you actually

27:27

have to pay money that you

27:30

wouldn't otherwise pay,

27:32

I mean, that's much more

27:34

direct interference with the operations of the

27:36

bank. It seems to me maybe

27:39

you have an explanation. Well, then Bank of America,

27:41

it has, you know, would be able to try

27:43

to carry its burden of establishing that standard.

27:45

Isn't that just, I mean, do you need a

27:47

trial? It's just common sense, isn't it? Tell

27:50

someone you have to pay out large

27:53

sums of money collectively rather

27:56

than how you describe your product and

27:58

your advertising. Isn't one more significant? and

28:00

interference than the other at the prices. I'll

28:02

take the Franklin side of that question first,

28:04

if I may. So just to be clear

28:06

about the law in Franklin, it went well

28:09

beyond advertising, and it disabled banks from even

28:11

being able to use the word savings on

28:14

their deposit slips anywhere in their bank

28:16

offices. It just eradicated the word

28:18

or any of its equivalents from the

28:20

premises of the bank. And I think

28:23

what made, you might think

28:25

about that as posing a First Amendment problem

28:27

today. It was also a discriminatory law that

28:29

gave certain state institutions the ability to use

28:31

that word. And so it posed a number

28:33

of distinct problems, but I think ultimately too,

28:35

it posed a conflict with

28:38

the text of the federal statute

28:40

because the state in that scenario

28:42

thought to significantly interfere with the

28:44

exercise and express statutory power of

28:46

the Congress. The advertising was not

28:48

an express power. The advertising, the

28:50

court made clear, was an incidental

28:52

power. Right, but the power that

28:54

I think, ultimately the court focused on, was

28:56

the express power to accept savings deposits, and

28:58

in particular the use of the word savings,

29:01

I think, was critical to the court's analysis.

29:03

Right, and here the express power is the

29:05

lending, and the incidental

29:07

power is the escrow accounts, correct?

29:10

The way that Bank of America articulates the

29:12

power, we're not disputing their articulation of the

29:14

power for purposes of this court's

29:17

decision, is the power to

29:19

offer mortgage escrow accounts to

29:21

consumers. So

29:24

the question is, to the extent to which the

29:26

law significantly interferes with that power. And

29:29

do you still think McCulloch versus Maryland was correctly

29:31

decided? Yeah, we have no issue with McCulloch, and

29:33

I think we want to answer that question. Why

29:36

is that correctly decided and that's different? So

29:38

we point to this in our brief,

29:40

but there are a couple of key

29:42

distinctions. So that case involved a tax,

29:44

a discriminatory tax, on the

29:47

Second Bank of the United States. And

29:49

I think at that time, the Second Bank

29:51

of the United States functioned more like the

29:53

Federal Reserve Bank, and it had

29:55

a really public facing component. And

29:57

it doesn't, modern national.

30:00

banks don't really resemble the Second Bank of

30:02

the United States. And the laws

30:04

that we have, in this case,

30:06

are not discriminatory laws. And in any

30:08

event, it's a question of preemption, and

30:10

it's ultimately Congress that lays down the

30:12

standard, and the standard is prevents or

30:14

significantly interferes with. Thank you. Justice

30:17

Barrett. Counsel, you're drawing a

30:19

distinction, which I also saw in your

30:22

brief between express powers and incidental

30:25

powers. Can you just explain to

30:27

me why that matters? And I'll tell you kind

30:29

of where I'm going with it or why I'm

30:31

thinking about it. It almost sounds to me, and

30:33

correct me if I'm wrong, that you're saying that

30:35

if a power is expressed, that

30:38

something more like a control test might

30:40

apply just as a matter of economic

30:42

logic, say. But that if

30:45

it's incidental, and you would characterize this

30:47

one, I gather as incidental that we

30:49

get into this more fact-specific inquiry. Am

30:52

I understanding your position? I think you're right

30:54

to point out that we do underscore the

30:56

fact that this is an incidental power, so

30:58

that Congress hasn't said anything specific on the

31:00

subject. And indeed, it's a kind of second

31:02

order incidental power that is an issue, which

31:04

is not just the ability to have the

31:06

accounts, but then to set the interest rate.

31:09

And so I think the reason why

31:11

we're focusing on that is preemption questions typically turn on

31:13

what Congress says in the text of the statute. And

31:15

so you want to look at the text of

31:17

the statute. And this court in Barnett Bank, right

31:20

before the sentence that articulates the

31:22

standard as prevents or significantly interferes

31:25

with, says that the relevant power is

31:27

the power that quote, Congress explicitly granted.

31:29

Now, what's interesting here is the National

31:31

Bank Act actually expressly grants incidental powers.

31:34

And so there is an express grant of

31:37

authority to National Bank to engage

31:40

in incidental powers. But the

31:42

ultimate question I think has to

31:44

focus on what Congress has said in the text

31:46

of the statute. Well, I mean,

31:48

I do agree with that. But you've characterized

31:50

Barnett Bank a couple times as kind of

31:52

an express conflict. But Barnett Bank goes

31:55

out of its way to say we don't have

31:57

an irreconcilable conflict there. It

32:00

wasn't the kind of situation where you

32:02

had the federal statute saying, you know, do

32:04

X, the state statute saying not X. And

32:07

so it was about significant interference, and I

32:09

don't read Barnet Bank to be applying

32:11

this kind of fact-specific inquiry that you're

32:13

talking about. So is the difference really just

32:15

that the statute said something express? Well,

32:19

so in Barnet Bank, you're right that

32:21

there was an impossibility preemption. So it

32:23

wasn't impossible for the bank to both

32:25

comply with the federal statute and the

32:27

state statute. The court did say

32:29

that there was an express conflict based on the

32:31

text of the statute. And so

32:33

it really, the irony is Barnet Bank

32:35

announced the standard which it distilled from

32:37

this court's cases, but it really didn't

32:39

have occasion to flesh out the contours

32:41

of what significant interference means because it

32:43

involved a complete prohibition. And so, but

32:45

the court left no indication in its opinion

32:48

that if the law and issue in that

32:50

case were less than a complete prohibition, that

32:52

it would automatically be preempted under the

32:54

control test. To the contrary, even the

32:57

bank in Barnet Bank, at oral argument,

32:59

conceded that a whole bunch of state

33:01

regulations would be appropriate as

33:03

to the regulation of insurance, including ensuring that

33:07

agents of insurance are licensed

33:09

at the state level. And so I think

33:11

I don't read this court's opinion to suggest

33:14

that practical effects aren't relevant. To

33:16

the contrary, I think by using significant interference,

33:18

the court understood that practical effects would matter,

33:21

and what it was trying to capture as

33:23

law is that even if they didn't completely

33:25

prohibit the exercise of the National Bank's powers,

33:27

they would do something that would raise the

33:29

same kind of concern in practical effect. And

33:31

the first case the court cited after it

33:33

announced that standard was Anderson, which can only

33:35

be understood as turning on the practical effect

33:37

of the law. Thanks.

33:40

Justice Jackson? So I see the

33:42

standard significantly interferes in

33:44

the actual text of the

33:46

statute, and I'm trying

33:49

to understand whether this really

33:51

is sort of an unusual

33:53

or unworkable assignment for the

33:55

courts. So can you help

33:57

me to sort of contemplate? how,

34:02

if at all, this

34:04

significantly interfered standard is

34:06

any different from,

34:08

you know, similar

34:10

standards in other statutes. So last

34:13

term in Roth,

34:15

we looked at a statute that

34:17

asks whether religious accommodation would

34:19

impose a, quote, undue

34:22

hardship on the conduct

34:24

of the employer's business. So

34:27

Roth imposes a, quote, substantial

34:29

burden test. So isn't this

34:32

sort of in the nature

34:34

of statutory standards of this kind

34:36

and the court looks at them and

34:38

we make a decision? Absolutely, Justice Chalkman.

34:40

That's correct. All right. And

34:42

then with respect to the arduous

34:44

nature of this and sort of,

34:46

you know, what has

34:48

to be proven, I guess I'm wondering, doesn't

34:52

what is necessary to

34:54

be established to meet this standard depend

34:56

on the reason that the bank says

34:59

the statutory standard is being

35:01

met in a particular case. So, you know,

35:03

the bank says we are pointing

35:05

to this preemption provision and we

35:07

say that it's, that

35:10

what is going on here with

35:12

this state law significantly interferes with

35:14

our powers and then I

35:16

guess they go on to say how,

35:18

how is that happening? So when they

35:21

say this significantly interferes with my powers

35:23

because it directly conflicts with

35:25

what the statute says about

35:27

our authority, which is what I

35:29

understood was happening in, you know,

35:31

Barnett, Ripbank and Franklin, then

35:34

I guess the court doesn't have to have a bunch

35:36

of depositions or anything. They're doing sort of

35:38

a statutory analysis. Is that right? That's right.

35:41

All right. And when they

35:43

say instead this significantly interferes with

35:45

my power because it imposes an

35:47

undue burden, I

35:50

suppose the bank would then be charged by

35:52

the court with proving that.

35:55

How burdensome is this? What, what, give me

35:57

evidence says the court. Am I right about

35:59

that? Correct. And so similarly,

36:01

if it significantly interferes, if they say

36:03

it's a significant interference, again, we're in

36:06

the realm of evidence. And

36:08

we're doing this on a case-by-case basis because that's what the

36:11

statute says you have to do. Correct.

36:13

All right. Thank you. Thank

36:16

you, counsel. Mr. Stewart. Thank

36:18

you, Mr. Chief Justice, and may it

36:20

please the Court. I'd like to make

36:23

three quick points before taking questions. The

36:25

first is that the Court shouldn't assume

36:27

that the word significantly either in the

36:30

opinion of the Court in

36:32

Barnett Bank or in the statute itself

36:34

is devoid of significance. If Congress wanted

36:36

a statute that said state law is

36:38

preempted when it forces the bank to

36:40

deviate in any way from what it

36:42

would otherwise do, it wouldn't have used

36:44

the word significantly. It would have used

36:46

another formulation. Second, in Franklin National Bank,

36:48

the Court didn't suggest that all

36:50

state law restrictions on national bank

36:53

advertising were preempted. It emphasized that

36:55

the word savings was the very

36:57

word that Congress had used in

37:00

the statutes to describe the product

37:02

at issue and that

37:04

it was the very word that

37:06

in consumers' minds was most closely

37:08

linked to the product. And as

37:10

Mr. Taylor explained, at trial, the

37:13

bank in that case presented extensive

37:15

evidence that it would be

37:17

hindered in its ability to obtain

37:19

savings accounts if it couldn't use that word. And

37:22

last I'd say the Court should look

37:24

not only at Franklin, the case the

37:26

Court cited in Barnett Bank as an

37:28

example of a preempted statute, but also

37:30

at Anderson National Bank. And Anderson National

37:32

Bank involved a state abandoned deposit law.

37:35

It authorized the state to take over

37:37

the deposit, force the bank to turn

37:39

over a deposit to

37:41

the state upon proof that the account

37:43

had been inactive for a specified

37:46

period of time. And it's hard to imagine a

37:48

more direct interference with the bank's

37:50

ability to do business than telling the bank,

37:52

you would prefer to hold the money and

37:54

earn income on it, but we require you

37:57

to turn it over to us. for

38:00

various reasons that this would not

38:02

substantially interfere with the way the

38:04

bank did business. I welcome the

38:06

court's questions. Mr.

38:09

Stewart, is

38:12

there a difference in the treatment

38:14

of incidental powers versus

38:16

the express power you mentioned

38:18

in Franklin? I don't think

38:20

generally. Incidental

38:23

powers are powers, as you know,

38:25

that are not enumerated in the

38:27

statute and interference with an incidental

38:31

power can cause indirect harm

38:35

to the bank's ability to exercise the express

38:38

power. I would point out that

38:41

the court in Barnett Bank, in

38:43

the sentence immediately preceding the one

38:45

that we've been focused on, said

38:47

the prior cases, the ones that

38:49

have found preemption, take the view

38:51

that normally Congress would not want

38:53

states to forbid or to impair

38:55

significantly the exercise of a power

38:57

that Congress explicitly granted.

39:00

It was focusing on express powers there,

39:03

and it was saying even with respect

39:05

to express powers, the impairment

39:07

has to be significant. The

39:11

control test doesn't apply to express powers.

39:13

I don't think there's a meaningful difference.

39:15

Counsel, do you agree with your friend

39:17

that determining whether something is significant would

39:20

be something you can do without trial

39:23

evidence? Certainly if the

39:25

OCC were doing it, it would have

39:27

kind of a pre-existing body of information

39:29

about the way the national banks operate,

39:31

and it might be able to draw

39:33

on that font

39:36

of experience in determining whether restrictions

39:38

that might seem innocuous to a

39:40

layperson could in fact predictably have

39:42

a significant adverse effect on the

39:45

bank's business. I think Mr. Taylor

39:47

was also alluding to the court's

39:49

decision in Morales, which involved the

39:51

Airline Deregulation Act, in which the

39:54

court explained how the

39:56

state false advertising law would

39:59

impair the airlines' ability to engage

40:01

in the pricing practices that they wanted

40:03

to engage in. And the court didn't

40:05

make quite clear exactly where the information

40:07

about the pricing practices came from, but

40:09

it didn't appear to come from a

40:11

trial record. So there may be kind

40:13

of sources of information other than trial

40:15

evidence that would allow the court of

40:17

the – I'm sorry. Mr.

40:19

Stewart, that raises a question for me,

40:21

because like the Chief Justice, I was

40:23

wondering, you know, what could the OCC

40:25

do here? And you alluded to that.

40:28

It's interesting. I'm not sure what

40:31

to make of this, but in the

40:33

13 years or so since Dodd-Frank, we

40:36

don't have an OCCA rule on escrow

40:38

accounts except for the one issued in

40:40

2011, immediately after Dodd-Frank,

40:44

in which it reaffirmed its

40:47

rule banning, as I understand

40:49

it, any regulation by states

40:51

on escrow accounts under an

40:53

obstruct or impair standard that

40:55

predated Dodd-Frank that purported

40:57

to ratify what it had done before

41:00

under the old law. And

41:03

as I took it from a couple of cryptic

41:05

footnotes in your brief, you're

41:07

not asking us to defer to that regulation.

41:10

In fact, you seem to suggest that it's

41:12

inconsistent with the law and entitled to

41:14

no respect. Why hasn't the OCC

41:17

done something here under the law that

41:19

actually exists? Well, the OCC

41:21

did file an amicus brief in the Second

41:23

Circuit taking – The other way.

41:26

Right. And so that

41:28

was what they did. Now I would –

41:30

And you seem to have disavowed everything the

41:32

OCC has done since Dodd-Frank. What

41:35

do we do with that? Well, I

41:37

think there are substantial indications in the

41:39

text and history of Dodd-Frank that although

41:41

Congress intended to codify

41:44

the Barnett Bank standard, it intended to

41:46

revise or overturn the way that the

41:48

OCC had been making – And then

41:50

the OCC said, maybe you thought so,

41:52

but we promulgated it before

41:55

Dodd-Frank, so you're stuck with it. And

41:57

now you're saying, nah, that's not right. Is

42:00

the OCC going to actually do some of this work

42:02

at some point? As

42:04

far as I'm aware, the OCC has

42:06

never issued a case-by-case preemption

42:09

determination. I don't know

42:11

what the reason is, but I would say

42:14

if you imagine the OCC trying to do

42:16

a case-by-case preemption determination with respect to the

42:18

New York law at issue here, the

42:21

most straightforward way to do it would

42:23

simply be to say, we have a

42:25

regulation that says states can't regulate mortgage

42:27

escrow accounts. This is a regulation of

42:29

mortgage escrow accounts, therefore it's preempted. And

42:31

if the OCC tried to do it

42:34

that way, it would run into the

42:36

provisions of Dodd-Frank that say when the

42:38

OCC does these determinations, it considers the

42:41

impact of the state law. In fact,

42:43

we have exactly the regulation you say

42:45

if they did this. They did it.

42:48

They said there are no escrow regulations

42:50

that are permissible under state law.

42:52

They're all preempted. But you're not

42:54

defending that regulation. You're disavowing it. You're going

42:56

to have to flip-flop positions on it. And

42:58

I'm asking, is the OCC ever

43:00

going to get around to doing that which Dodd-Frank

43:03

directs it to do? Well, I

43:05

think I would say Dodd-Frank authorizes

43:07

but doesn't direct it to do this.

43:09

Now, if the petitioner's

43:11

position in this case prevails,

43:14

and if the court holds that

43:16

some inquiry into practical impacts is

43:18

necessary with respect to the individual

43:20

state law, then it's

43:22

very possible that the OCC will

43:25

start making these case-by-case determinations. Because

43:27

independent of legal expertise, the OCC

43:29

has expertise in the way that

43:31

national banks operate and can bring

43:34

that expertise to bear in determining...

43:37

If it has expertise, why are you

43:39

disagreeing with its longstanding position? I think

43:41

the two or three reasons. The

43:44

first is that, as

43:47

I say, we think that the text of

43:49

Dodd-Frank manifests a disapproval by

43:51

Congress of the way that OCC

43:53

had been doing these determinations. The

43:56

text says case-by-case determinations, and it's

43:58

really the opposite. of an OCC

44:00

rule that says here are many

44:02

categories of state laws that

44:04

can't be enforced at all. Even though the

44:06

key members said otherwise. They

44:09

were not the key members. They were two

44:11

members of the Senate who had drafted the

44:13

Senate version of the preemption. I shouldn't have

44:16

used the, but key members. I shouldn't have

44:18

used the word the. They

44:21

had drafted the Senate version of the preemption

44:23

provision, and the Senate version

44:25

contained a general reference to the

44:28

legal standard in Barnett Bank, but

44:30

didn't use the phrase prevents or

44:32

significantly interferes with. And

44:34

then the House bill had

44:37

framed the preemption standard as does the

44:39

state law prevent. I interrupted you. Keep going

44:41

with why you change positions. So once the

44:43

year of reading the text in history. That

44:46

they indicate that Congress wanted the OCC

44:48

to redo this. I think the second

44:50

thing that we would say is

44:53

the way in which OCC's view is

44:55

currently manifested is in the 2011 regulations.

44:59

But Congress said the way that

45:02

OCC is supposed

45:04

to do preemption determinations going forward

45:06

is through case by case determinations.

45:08

And historically it's been a requirement

45:11

for deference that the agency act

45:13

through the procedural mechanism that Congress

45:15

specified. The third thing is Congress

45:17

said even when the OCC does

45:19

case by case determinations, it only

45:21

gets Skidmore deference. It doesn't use

45:23

the word Skidmore, but it basically

45:25

tracks language from Skidmore. And then

45:27

it says nothing in

45:29

the proceeding sub-paragraph alters

45:32

the deference that OCC gets for

45:34

any other type of determination. And

45:36

so it seemed clear that Congress

45:38

was happy with the way that OCC

45:40

had been doing things in all respects

45:42

other than preemption, but not with

45:45

the way it had been doing. Stuart,

45:49

do you have a view on whether

45:51

this New York statute constitutes a significant

45:53

interference with national bank empowers? We

45:56

don't have a concluded view. Certainly

45:58

as Mr. Taylor points out, this

46:00

is... something that state banks have

46:02

been complying with, apparently without material

46:04

impairment. I

46:07

think it would depend in part

46:09

on evidence or a factual showing

46:12

about what rate of interest

46:14

can the banks use on the money in

46:16

the escrow account because- Can I

46:18

interpret that, may I? Sure. Can

46:20

I interpret that as suggesting that you're

46:22

skeptical, that it's a significant interference? Yes.

46:25

Okay. Justice Thomas, anything

46:28

for Justice Alito? Well,

46:30

suppose the OCC doesn't act

46:34

and suppose a bank says that requiring

46:36

us to pay 2% interest

46:39

or whatever rate of interest is involved

46:42

in the particular case costs us this amount

46:44

of money and if we have to pay

46:46

this additional amount of money in

46:49

interest, then we're not going to be

46:51

able to, we're not

46:53

going to continue to do this or that. How

46:57

would a court determine whether that is significant?

47:00

I mean, I think it, I would come

47:03

harken back to the point that Justice Jackson was

47:05

making that there are

47:07

many standards in the law that require this sort,

47:09

and they're imprecise, but I think the court would

47:11

ask how significant is

47:14

the other thing that the bank says it wouldn't

47:16

be able to do? Well, I mean, the most

47:18

of those, I can't remember the whole list, most

47:20

of those did not involve economic

47:23

determinations. I

47:26

mean, certainly as Mr. Taylor points out, it

47:28

can't be sufficient that a state

47:30

law would require the bank to

47:32

spend some amount of money on

47:34

something. I'd point

47:37

out, in fact, that federal

47:40

law, can you

47:42

quantify significant interference? I

47:44

just don't, you know, maybe this ruling

47:47

the way you want us to rule will not

47:49

cause any problems at all, but I'd appreciate it

47:51

if you would talk about the

47:53

argument that this will cause a

47:55

lot of problems. There's the imprecision

47:57

of the significant interference standard. It

48:00

does seem to have a very strong factual

48:03

component. I

48:07

find it hard to understand how an

48:10

empirical question like that can be

48:12

decided without evidence, which

48:17

would require discovery and perhaps testimony

48:20

by experts, it would require individual

48:22

district court judges to make the

48:25

kind of, I mean, certainly when

48:27

the OCC does this, they can

48:29

call on a lot of economic

48:31

expertise and knowledge of the banking

48:33

industry. Every district judge in the

48:36

country is potentially gonna

48:38

have to make the same

48:40

kind of determination. And

48:42

then there's the problem that these cases

48:45

are gonna be decided on an

48:47

individual record. So suppose these petitioners

48:49

lose on this record,

48:52

would that ban others who

48:55

have non-interest bearing accounts with the

48:57

Bank of America from being, bringing

48:59

suit and saying we can compile

49:02

a better record. And then you

49:04

have questions about the same issue

49:07

being decided in different circuits.

49:10

What if other states have required

49:12

2% interest and the

49:15

second circuit says one thing and the

49:17

fifth circuit or the 10th circuit or

49:19

whatever says something else. And then you

49:21

have issues of collateral estoppel. It does

49:24

seem like a complicated situation, you

49:27

are able to assess the whole thing. So

49:29

just explain why this would not

49:32

cause practical nightmares. I

49:35

guess for two reasons. The first is

49:37

that administration of standards like this is

49:40

routine in the law and the banks

49:42

obviously have access to a lot of

49:44

information that I don't have access to

49:47

about the ways in which particular state

49:49

laws would affect their operations. The

49:52

Flagstar-Amicus brief has a fairly

49:55

intricate argument about how these

49:57

sorts of laws would impair its ability to secure.

50:00

curatize loans and so forth.

50:02

But the second thing I would say, and

50:04

Mr. Taylor alluded to this, is we also

50:07

have non-discrimination as a backstop. And

50:09

that gets rid of the horribles,

50:11

that gets rid of the extreme

50:13

cases. In some instances, taxation, for

50:15

instance, under current federal law,

50:18

states can tax national banks so long

50:20

as they do it on a non-discriminatory

50:22

basis. The court in Barnett Bank pointed

50:24

out that national banks can

50:26

operate branches only to the extent

50:28

that it's permissible for state. I

50:30

understand that, but all you've said about the

50:32

question when you put non-discrimination off the table

50:34

because that's not what's at issue. All you've

50:36

said is that there are other

50:39

statutes that impose a similar burden

50:41

on the court. And I mean,

50:43

the one I remember from Justice

50:45

Jackson's question is the undue burden

50:48

standard in Title VII. That's

50:51

quite a bit different. What's the, do you have

50:53

any that are closer to this? A

50:56

lot of economic determination? I

50:59

don't really, other than the ones that

51:01

Mr. Taylor was alluding to that are

51:03

involved cases citing in his reply brief,

51:05

who are often under statutes like the

51:08

Airline Deregulation Act. There's a core of

51:10

things that are clearly preempted, but then

51:12

when you decide where does the boundary

51:15

of preemption lie, you're looking at practical

51:17

impacts. And it involves- Thank you. But-

51:20

Justice Sotomayor? Questions.

51:25

I understand my

51:27

colleagues, some of my colleagues' concerns

51:29

about this case by case approach.

51:32

But I go back to the text, which is

51:34

the text permits the states to do this and

51:38

says unless, and it's the unless

51:40

that's creating this problem, but the

51:42

presumption is that there's no preemption,

51:44

correct? That's correct. And the point

51:46

I was making about discrimination is,

51:48

even if you assume kind of

51:51

the worst case scenario, that this

51:53

all becomes so complicated that banks

51:55

decide it's just not worth trying

51:57

to establish preemption under prevention significantly

51:59

interferes. are still left

52:01

with substantial protection against discriminatory laws,

52:03

which in other aspects ... Can

52:06

we go to inherent

52:09

injustice, Kavanaugh's earlier

52:11

question of

52:13

co-counsel, and

52:15

he said you're costing

52:18

the banks money, and

52:20

that's a greater burden than it was

52:22

in Franklin. Now,

52:24

you point out Anderson, which it costs

52:26

them money too. So

52:29

do you have an

52:32

argument as to why his saying

52:34

that Franklin sets a sort of maximum

52:37

or a minimum is a

52:39

wrong way to look at this? Well, Franklin didn't

52:41

cost the bank money in the sense of forcing

52:43

it to make outlays, but it cost the bank

52:45

money in the sense of making

52:48

it more difficult for the bank to

52:50

attract customers and thereby earn money

52:52

on the accounts. That is, the bank

52:54

officers testified it was more difficult to

52:57

get consumers to sign up for savings

52:59

accounts if you couldn't use the word

53:01

savings in your pitch. They

53:03

had consumer surveys that showed that

53:05

consumers were more likely to

53:07

recognize the word savings. No, I understand that.

53:10

And so I think it would be,

53:13

for these purposes, an artificial distinction to

53:15

draw a line between state laws that

53:17

require the state to lay out money

53:20

and state laws that simply make it

53:22

more difficult for the state to earn

53:24

money. Well, that's an answer why it's not

53:26

a significant interference or how do you

53:28

measure that when it's costing

53:30

the bank money? I mean, one thing you

53:33

would want to look at is to what

53:35

extent could the bank earn money on the

53:37

escrow account and what

53:40

relationship would that potential earning have

53:43

to the interest it was required to pay out? Because

53:46

when people defend the use of escrow

53:49

accounts in this setting, it's never on

53:51

the ground that it's a good way

53:53

for banks to earn a little money.

53:55

It's on the ground that it protects

53:57

the bank's collateral against the possibility of

53:59

failure. failure to pay taxes, failure to

54:02

maintain insurance, and escrow accounts are very

54:04

useful for those purposes. So in essence,

54:07

you're almost saying this would be an easy

54:09

case to prove. If they can earn 5%,

54:11

then they just have to give up two.

54:14

There's no substantial interference. That

54:18

would certainly be right. I think the

54:20

more difficult. If they can't earn any

54:22

money on this money, and

54:25

they have to pay out, that might be. Yes,

54:27

then you're at least trying

54:30

to determine whether that mandatory

54:32

outlay is significant. Okay.

54:35

Justice Kagan. Mr. Seward, it might be that

54:37

you have text on your side, but before

54:39

we get to that question, I

54:41

guess I'm interested in many of the inquiries

54:44

that Justice Alito was making, and I'll just

54:46

come at it a slightly different way. Yes,

54:49

significant tests are common in the

54:52

law, but they're not really common

54:54

in preemption inquiries. We don't

54:56

really see a whole lot of

54:58

preemption inquiries where we have to

55:00

do this question of like, how

55:02

much is too much? And

55:04

one reason we don't is

55:08

you need an answer that applies everywhere

55:10

and for all time. I mean, significant

55:12

effects. You could have a no significant effect

55:15

now, and then 10 years from now, you're

55:17

in a different economic environment, and you could

55:19

have a significant effect. And does that mean

55:21

it would be a kind of on-off switch,

55:24

like one day the law applies, and the

55:26

next day 10 years

55:28

later it doesn't? So add to

55:30

Justice Alito's question about maybe

55:33

different parties would present different records.

55:35

Maybe different states would have the

55:37

exact same law, but the economic

55:39

circumstances in those two states would

55:41

be very different. So it looks

55:43

as though the federal law preempts

55:45

one state law and doesn't preempt

55:47

the other state law. It seems

55:49

an odd kind of inquiry for

55:51

a preemption question. I guess

55:54

the first thing I would say is, and I'd point

55:56

the court to the cases cited at the back end

55:58

of Mr. Taylor's reply. that

56:00

talk about statutes like the Airline

56:02

Deregulation Act, which preempts state laws

56:05

relating to rates, routes, and services.

56:07

And if you have a state

56:09

law that specifies what rates or

56:11

routes or services the airline can

56:13

use, that's an easy case. That's

56:16

preempted without regard to practical impacts.

56:18

But the Court has also recognized

56:20

sometimes states will regulate something else,

56:22

but the regulation of something else

56:24

will have a predictable spillover effect

56:27

on the airline's ability to pursue

56:30

the rates, routes, and services that they

56:32

want. And it's in those cases at

56:34

the border of preemption where the courts

56:36

have been forced into pragmatic inquiries. And

56:38

as I say, the second point I

56:40

would make about the text is there

56:43

were other formulations Congress could have chosen.

56:45

Some statutes refer to... Yeah, I guess

56:47

you're not giving me a whole lot

56:49

of comfort in this about how peculiar

56:51

this would be, that we could have

56:53

different rules in different states. We

56:56

could have different rules depending on

56:59

the time that the challenge is brought.

57:02

I think that's A, something that

57:04

Congress signed up for, but B, it's

57:06

really a benefit to the banks. That

57:08

is, if Congress had prized

57:11

ease of administration above all else,

57:13

it could simply have rested on

57:15

the anti-discrimination prong, as it has

57:17

with respect to other aspects of

57:20

national bank operations. And by adding

57:25

prong B of the preemption standard,

57:27

Congress is giving an additional opportunity to

57:29

the banks to say, even though the

57:32

states are doing this to their own

57:34

state chartered banks as well, it will

57:36

significantly impair our operations. They can invoke

57:38

it or not invoke it as they

57:40

want, but it's an additional opportunity for

57:42

the banks. Thank you.

57:45

Justice Gorsuch? Justice Cavanaugh?

57:48

In Barnett, the statutory text directs us

57:50

to Barnett, so I've been trying to

57:52

parse Barnett even more than usual. And

57:55

I have a question about the two paragraphs

57:57

after the articulation of the standard. the

58:00

court in Barnett said, where

58:03

Congress is not expressly conditioned

58:05

to the grant of power upon

58:07

a grant of state permission, the

58:09

court has ordinarily found that no

58:11

such condition applies,

58:15

then says in Franklin National Bank, the

58:17

court made this point explicit. The

58:22

federal statute before us, as in Franklin National

58:24

Bank explicitly grants the National

58:26

Bank an authorization permission or power,

58:28

it contains no indication that Congress

58:30

intended to subject that power to

58:32

local restriction. What do you,

58:34

how do you interpret those? I'm

58:37

sorry, I have the pages here, but can you,

58:41

say, well, I'll say the last

58:43

sentence again. And as in Franklin

58:45

National Bank, it contains no indication

58:47

that Congress intended to subject that

58:49

power to local restriction. Thus,

58:52

I'll give you one more sentence. Thus,

58:54

the court's discussion in Franklin, the holding

58:56

of that case and the other precedent

58:59

we've cited above strongly argue for a

59:01

similar interpretation here, a broad

59:03

interpretation of the word may that does

59:05

not condition federal permission upon that of

59:07

the state. Yes, I think the court

59:09

there was referring to one

59:11

of the arguments that Florida made in the

59:13

case. And as Mr. Taylor was pointing out

59:16

that the conflict in Franklin was very stark.

59:18

The federal statute said, national

59:20

banks may sell insurance in small towns.

59:22

The state statute said that you

59:25

can't. And perhaps out of desperation,

59:27

the state argued that, well, when

59:29

the federal statute says national banks

59:31

may sell insurance in

59:33

small towns, it only means they may

59:35

do this if state law allows it.

59:37

And the court said, that's not the

59:39

way we usually understand federal

59:42

authorizations to work. That

59:44

ordinarily, if the

59:47

national bank act says you can do something

59:49

and state law says you can't, the federal

59:51

statute controls. Two more

59:54

questions, apologies. If

59:56

you follow up on what Justice Gorsuch said, Dodd-Frank

59:59

does... explicitly require

1:00:01

payment of interest for certain kinds of

1:00:04

escrow accounts. Given

1:00:07

the OCC history and

1:00:10

Congress's involvement, Congress explicitly requiring

1:00:12

that for certain kinds would

1:00:14

suggest something

1:00:16

else for these. How

1:00:19

do you respond to that? The

1:00:21

statute says that for these

1:00:23

mandatory accounts, accounts that are mandated

1:00:25

by TILA, the

1:00:28

bank must pay interest under

1:00:30

applicable state or federal law.

1:00:33

There's a question about what applicable means.

1:00:35

Certainly with respect to applicable federal law,

1:00:37

it would mean you'd have to point

1:00:40

to some other federal statute that required

1:00:42

interest to be paid on the escrow

1:00:44

accounts. I think one

1:00:47

natural reading of that provision would be

1:00:49

it doesn't establish a special rule for

1:00:51

TILA mandated accounts. It

1:00:54

just says if you would be

1:00:56

required to pay interest on this account

1:00:58

were it voluntarily created, you have to do

1:01:00

it at the same time. Last question. You

1:01:02

said earlier I think the

1:01:05

banks could do this without material

1:01:07

impairment. I think you predicted that. Yes.

1:01:10

We certainly have not seen anything up

1:01:12

to this point that suggests that a

1:01:15

bank could not pay this rate.

1:01:18

It's higher costs therefore decreasing the

1:01:20

availability of credit or higher rates

1:01:22

that they charge. Is that material

1:01:25

impairment or not and how do we assess

1:01:28

that? Certainly out of pocket expense in and

1:01:30

of itself wouldn't be sufficient but they would

1:01:32

have to not just assert but make a

1:01:34

showing that this would be

1:01:36

a deterrent to their meaningful

1:01:39

practical deterrent to their offering other services.

1:01:42

Thank you. Justice Barrett.

1:01:44

Mr. Surratt, do you understand case

1:01:46

by case basis to refer to

1:01:48

bank by bank basis or to

1:01:50

statute by statute basis? Statute by

1:01:52

statute basis and the statute says

1:01:55

the OCC can extend its inquiry

1:01:57

beyond the specific state statute. a

1:02:00

substantively equivalent state law. In

1:02:03

our view, reinforces the sense

1:02:06

that it's statute by statute, not case

1:02:08

by case, but date by

1:02:10

date. Do you think that this language,

1:02:12

case by case, and just looking in the statute,

1:02:14

do you think it is designed to

1:02:16

say something about how courts conduct the

1:02:19

preemption inquiry as in this

1:02:21

case because it was brought by court versus the

1:02:23

control of the currency? Because I'm just looking at

1:02:25

the way that it's structured.

1:02:28

It says any

1:02:31

preemption determination under this paragraph may be made

1:02:33

by a court, or by regulation or order

1:02:35

of the control of the currency on a

1:02:38

case by case basis, and then all of

1:02:40

the subsequent references to case by case basis

1:02:43

refer to the OCC determination. And

1:02:46

I'm just asking, should I make anything of that? The

1:02:49

two things you should make of it are, first,

1:02:51

yes, it is directed just to the OCC, and

1:02:54

it seems to have been a

1:02:56

reaction to the 2004 OCC regulations,

1:02:58

which declared broad categories

1:03:01

of state law to be off the

1:03:03

table. Yes. And Congress

1:03:05

was saying, don't do it that way. Focus

1:03:08

on the impacts of a particular state law.

1:03:10

Totally agree, which is how I read it. So

1:03:13

I'm wondering how much it just seems to

1:03:15

me, I'll try to get to the point

1:03:17

of why I'm wondering about it. It seems

1:03:19

like that phrase, case by case basis, itself

1:03:21

sounds fact laden, like we're making factual determinations

1:03:23

on a case by case basis, but if

1:03:25

that language, case by case basis, was designed

1:03:27

to stop the OCC from doing what you're

1:03:29

saying, does it really

1:03:31

care that implication here? Well, I mean, under

1:03:34

Article III case or controversy principles, the

1:03:36

courts are already going to be subject

1:03:39

to this. By case by case basis.

1:03:41

Case by case basis, and the most

1:03:43

relevant language in that provision is that

1:03:45

in making a case by case determination,

1:03:47

the OCC must consider the impact of

1:03:50

the particular state law, and that seems

1:03:52

clearly to refer to the practical impact.

1:03:54

And if that's part of the substantive

1:03:56

inquiry, then even though the same case

1:03:58

by case requirement wouldn't apply to a

1:04:01

court, the court should consider impact as well.

1:04:03

So do you think the court then is

1:04:05

bound even though B3 is

1:04:07

referring to the Comptroller, do

1:04:10

you think the court should be implying the exact same

1:04:13

standard? I mean the

1:04:15

court is certainly bound by the same substantive

1:04:17

standard. If you look at B1. Well

1:04:19

B1, A, B and C of course, but

1:04:21

I took you to be referring to three

1:04:24

case by case basis definition

1:04:26

moving forward. No, I wouldn't. Again,

1:04:29

the court will be naturally looking at

1:04:31

a particular state law just because that's

1:04:33

what courts do. Congress didn't have to

1:04:35

worry that courts would kind

1:04:37

of announce broad lists of things that

1:04:39

couldn't be regulated. And so the court

1:04:42

should still consider the impact, the practical

1:04:44

impact, but it's not otherwise bound

1:04:46

by the procedural requirements. Of course.

1:04:48

So it just seems to me then that the court,

1:04:52

I guess what I'm saying is I'm not

1:04:54

sure how much of the talk about case

1:04:56

by case basis does for this question of

1:04:58

whether this is primary or legal or factual

1:05:00

inquiry for a court. I

1:05:05

would agree that the ultimate inquiry has

1:05:08

both factual and legal components. That is

1:05:10

you have to know the facts, but

1:05:12

you also have to make a legal

1:05:14

determination, do these facts amount to significant

1:05:16

interference. Thanks. Justice Jackson.

1:05:19

Going back to Justice Alito's

1:05:21

questions, is there a

1:05:23

reason why national banks can't

1:05:26

be subjected to the same kinds of

1:05:28

evidentiary standards that other plaintiffs

1:05:30

have to satisfy when they're making legal

1:05:32

claims? No. I mean, national

1:05:34

banks and because we are talking about not

1:05:37

the effect that this would have on somebody

1:05:39

else, but the effect it would have on

1:05:41

the national banks themselves, not only do they

1:05:43

have the wherewithal to satisfy these requirements, but

1:05:45

they're in the best position to have the

1:05:48

relevant information. And they have the wherewithal in

1:05:50

part because there's nothing that prevents national banks

1:05:52

from hiring lawyers and gathering

1:05:54

evidence and presenting them to the court, right?

1:05:56

Right. And is there

1:05:59

something about economic? economic questions that are not

1:06:01

within the competency of the court? No.

1:06:04

And I would ... I'm sorry. I

1:06:07

mean, doesn't the court litigate issues in

1:06:09

the realm of economic regulation all the

1:06:11

time? Sure. And

1:06:13

so I guess I'm wondering, is the

1:06:16

showing here

1:06:19

really any different than the other

1:06:21

standards that I'm talking about? So

1:06:23

for example, I mentioned the

1:06:25

undue burden standard in the Title VII

1:06:27

scenario. I mean, it would seem to

1:06:29

me that the showing that a company

1:06:31

employer would have to make

1:06:33

in Title VII regarding undue

1:06:36

burden on its business when accommodating

1:06:38

religious employers is really no different

1:06:40

in kind ... religious employees, excuse

1:06:42

me, is really no different in

1:06:44

kind than the kind

1:06:46

of thing a national bank would have

1:06:48

to show if it says this is

1:06:50

substantially interfering with my powers. All right.

1:06:54

So let

1:06:57

me ask you about how often

1:06:59

such a showing would have to

1:07:01

necessarily be made. Did I understand

1:07:03

you to say that the preemption

1:07:05

determination always requires an

1:07:07

evidentiary showing? I think

1:07:09

you kind of discussed that, but aren't

1:07:11

there circumstances in which a big evidentiary

1:07:13

showing wouldn't be necessary? Yes.

1:07:16

I mean, there certainly could be

1:07:18

cases in which the nature of the

1:07:20

restriction was ... has such

1:07:22

an obvious impact on the bank that you

1:07:24

wouldn't need at least any

1:07:26

... An obvious impact, for

1:07:29

example, like it's directly conflicting

1:07:31

with what Congress says about

1:07:33

the bank's powers. That would

1:07:35

be one example. Another example would

1:07:37

just be like charging a ... the

1:07:39

bank has to pay 15% or 20% interest rate.

1:07:43

Now, as Mr. Taylor pointed out, that's not going

1:07:45

to happen in the real world because states

1:07:47

are not going to impose restrictions on ...

1:07:49

like that on their own state charter banks. And

1:07:52

so the nondiscrimination requirement will take

1:07:55

off the table a lot of the most extreme ... This

1:07:58

isn't going to ... the big evidentiary showing problem is not going to happen. to happen

1:08:00

in every case in which the bank is

1:08:02

making a claim about preemption. That's correct. And

1:08:04

I'd also point out the bank, to

1:08:07

the extent at least it is worried about enforcement

1:08:09

by state officials, it doesn't have to wait

1:08:12

to be sued. That is, Barnett Bank was

1:08:14

a case in which the bank went into

1:08:16

court itself and sought a declaratory judgment of

1:08:18

preemption and that would be available. Bringing its

1:08:20

evidence and its lawyers and that sort of

1:08:22

thing. Yes. Finally,

1:08:24

with respect to Justice Kagan's question,

1:08:26

I guess I'm wondering what, if

1:08:29

anything we can do about

1:08:32

the oddity of the standard in this

1:08:34

context. It's in the statute. And

1:08:37

so I don't know whether we can just

1:08:39

read the statute to say something other than

1:08:41

it says because we think this is odd

1:08:44

to have it here. I

1:08:46

mean, we certainly agree that

1:08:48

you can read the statutory language in

1:08:50

light of the Barnett Bank opinion because

1:08:53

both because the statute... That tells you

1:08:55

you're supposed to do that. Both

1:08:58

by drawing specific language from Barnett

1:09:00

Bank and by including a separate

1:09:02

citation to Barnett Bank itself. But

1:09:05

I don't think the court can get

1:09:07

away from the fact that Congress

1:09:09

chose this particular formulation as its

1:09:11

distillation of the Barnett Bank opinion.

1:09:14

And that's because, as you said in the beginning,

1:09:17

significantly affect mean-sensing.

1:09:21

That Congress has actually used another formulation

1:09:24

if it just wants preemption

1:09:26

regarding any law that relates

1:09:28

to this. They say that

1:09:30

in ERISA, for example, it

1:09:32

says it's preempted if it

1:09:34

relates. Yes. And so that's easy

1:09:36

to apply, but here they didn't say that. And

1:09:40

some preemption provisions say a

1:09:43

state can't enforce a law that is

1:09:45

different from or in addition to the

1:09:47

requirements of federal law, meaning a state

1:09:49

can attach additional consequences to conduct that

1:09:51

already violates federal law but can't go

1:09:54

beyond that. And it didn't choose anything

1:09:56

like that here. Thank you. Thank

1:09:58

you, counsel. Thank you. Ms. Watt. Thank

1:10:02

you, Mr. Chief Justice, and may it please the Court. New

1:10:05

York law significantly interferes with the

1:10:07

exercise of national banking powers in

1:10:09

two respects. First, the law

1:10:11

controls the interest rate on mortgage accounts,

1:10:14

and second, a patchwork of 50 of

1:10:16

these state laws would unduly burden national

1:10:18

banks, destroying their uniform federal character. Now,

1:10:21

the other side posits that significantly interferes

1:10:24

requires factual proof that a state law

1:10:26

would hinder a banking power

1:10:28

to some unspecified degree. But

1:10:31

significantly interferes can be

1:10:33

both quantitative and qualitative. And

1:10:36

a state law that dictates the attributes of

1:10:38

a banking product interferes

1:10:41

with national banking power in a

1:10:43

qualitative effect, just as a court's

1:10:47

telling prosecutors what charges to bring

1:10:50

would significantly interfere with executive power.

1:10:54

The Barnett Bank uses the term significantly

1:10:56

interferes in a qualitative sense. Barnett Bank

1:10:58

reasons that state laws

1:11:00

are preempted absent any indication

1:11:02

that Congress intended to

1:11:05

subject the banking power to local

1:11:07

conditions. And here we know

1:11:09

Congress intended the opposite. First,

1:11:11

Congress, excuse me, federal law

1:11:13

comprehensively regulates state mortgage escrow

1:11:15

accounts in order to protect

1:11:17

consumers without requiring any interest.

1:11:20

And second, Congress speaks expressly when

1:11:22

it contemplates state interest laws. It

1:11:25

did so for state usury laws, and

1:11:27

Dodd-Frank itself requires interest on certain

1:11:30

mortgage escrow loans, but not

1:11:32

petitioners. It is

1:11:34

unfathomable that Congress intended the other side's

1:11:37

test. They never told you what

1:11:39

interest rate would be too much, what

1:11:41

to do when market forces change, and how

1:11:43

courts should proceed bank by bank. But

1:11:46

national banks need to know their regulatory obligations

1:11:48

ahead of time. It would

1:11:50

create seismic uncertainty if the laws of

1:11:52

50 states could apply to every banking

1:11:55

product and service, and not just

1:11:57

every feature of a mortgage, but

1:11:59

everything from from interest rates on

1:12:01

savings and checking accounts to ATM

1:12:03

fees to credit card reward programs.

1:12:05

Congress surely intended a preemption standard

1:12:08

that preserves the stability and predictability

1:12:10

that undergirds a safe and sound

1:12:12

banking system. Welcome questions.

1:12:15

Ms. Blatt, do we

1:12:17

treat express

1:12:20

banking powers the same as incidental

1:12:22

banking powers? It would seem that

1:12:24

you would have to somehow

1:12:30

have a way to fathom what

1:12:32

these incidental powers are. Right.

1:12:34

No. There's enumerated powers in

1:12:37

the 7th of 12 U.S.C.

1:12:39

24 and incidental powers

1:12:41

are defined as necessary powers to the

1:12:43

business of banking. I can't

1:12:45

think of them more. The only enumerated ones

1:12:47

are basically lend money, take deposits, and then

1:12:49

make real estate loans in 371. What

1:12:53

interest you charge is so fundamental to

1:12:55

a banking product and the banking power

1:12:57

that it would seem absurd to say

1:12:59

a state could dictate the interest rate on

1:13:01

something like a savings account just because that's

1:13:03

an incidental power. I agree with

1:13:05

you on that. In

1:13:08

Franklin, though, I think it was statutory.

1:13:11

It was expressed. But what

1:13:13

I'm more interested in is the

1:13:15

creation of an escrow account than

1:13:18

interest rate on the

1:13:20

escrow account, which is not sort

1:13:23

of the something the bank would normally

1:13:25

have to do. That's

1:13:28

correct. I mean, 13 state laws

1:13:30

require it since 1973. I

1:13:33

guess we've had the Real Estate Settlement Practice

1:13:35

Act that never required interest.

1:13:38

It's got 40,000 words

1:13:40

of regulation, 17 interpretive statements,

1:13:42

and 10 appendices regulating escrow accounts

1:13:44

and federal law. None of

1:13:47

it requires interest. I think the other side

1:13:49

would think states now could make amendments to

1:13:51

every single one of those requirements. Somehow,

1:13:54

banks would have to run and get declaratory

1:13:56

judgment as to each and every requirement

1:13:58

just on escrows. cascade that

1:14:00

across everything a bank does, it

1:14:03

is mind-boggling. It is mind-boggling how

1:14:05

many products and services national banks

1:14:07

do. And I'm not sure why

1:14:09

we're talking about God and the airlines in a national

1:14:11

banking case when we have 150 years

1:14:14

of precedent that culminates in Barnett

1:14:16

Bank. And you have 30 words

1:14:18

of text. You basically have Congress writing you

1:14:20

a love letter saying, we really like your Barnett

1:14:22

Bank decision. And then it

1:14:24

talks about the significant prevents or

1:14:26

significantly interfere. Barnett Bank

1:14:28

itself five times cites Franklin and

1:14:30

five times says what we mean by that

1:14:33

is we look to see if there's some

1:14:35

indication that Congress wanted to subject the power

1:14:39

of national banks to local conditions. I'm

1:14:41

sorry. There

1:14:44

are a meek eye in the logic

1:14:46

of the Second Circuit law would suggest

1:14:48

in your test, in the Second Circuit's

1:14:51

test, that no state consumer

1:14:54

law would be permitted. There's

1:14:57

an express permission for state consumer

1:14:59

laws. So which ones

1:15:01

are you going to say are OK?

1:15:05

All of them cost the

1:15:07

bank money, whether it's giving

1:15:09

a disclosure form or

1:15:11

a notice form, everything costs

1:15:14

money. So what's

1:15:16

incidental that

1:15:19

somehow wouldn't be preempted under the

1:15:21

Second Circuit test? Sure. Let

1:15:24

me tell you. The definition of state

1:15:26

consumer financial law versus the law that's

1:15:28

preempted under our test focuses on what

1:15:30

is being controlled. It's not simply is

1:15:32

state regulating. Of course, states are regulating.

1:15:34

But what is being controlled? Is it

1:15:36

the national banking power or is it

1:15:38

the financial transaction, in the words of

1:15:40

that definition with the consumer? And

1:15:43

when a state dictates- I'm sorry. What's

1:15:46

not controlling the financial transaction with

1:15:48

the consumer here? I'm going to give

1:15:50

you both the definition and a laundry list

1:15:52

of state law. The definition is this. When

1:15:55

the state dictates the attribute of the product

1:15:57

and service as opposed to the interaction with

1:15:59

the consumer. is preempted. And

1:16:01

under that definition, you

1:16:04

have banking specific laws that aren't

1:16:06

preempted, like laws that prohibit racial

1:16:08

discrimination and whatnot. You have laws

1:16:11

that prohibit fraud by banks. And

1:16:13

most importantly, you have the banking

1:16:15

specific cheat law in Anderson. That's

1:16:17

their leading case, and yet I

1:16:19

think it's our best case. The

1:16:21

court said that the only state

1:16:23

that what the state did, the

1:16:25

banking specific law, that it only

1:16:27

changed the identity of the account

1:16:29

holder who had the lawful right to demand

1:16:31

payment, i.e. the deposit account. But then five times

1:16:34

in the opinion, the court said, you are not,

1:16:36

the state law is not, and I'm going to

1:16:38

quote because they sit and rely on it, not

1:16:41

an unlawful encroachment on the rights and

1:16:43

privileges of national banks. It's not infringing

1:16:45

or interfering with any authorized function of

1:16:47

the bank. It's not a denial of

1:16:49

its privileges as a federal instrumentality and

1:16:52

so on. The other categories of laws

1:16:54

that are not preempted that meet the

1:16:56

definition of state consumer financial law are

1:16:58

all generally applicable laws that regulate

1:17:00

the manner and terms

1:17:02

of the financial transaction with the consumer.

1:17:04

So there's lots of, every state law

1:17:07

has a law of majority when you

1:17:09

can buy a mortgage. It's usually 18.

1:17:11

Alabama is 21. All

1:17:13

states have laws about when the statute of fraud

1:17:15

kicks in on what type of contracts. It's

1:17:18

not like I'm here making something up. The

1:17:21

National Bank Act was passed in 1864. In

1:17:25

1870, your first case that said

1:17:27

state law has room to play

1:17:29

on the dual banking system said

1:17:31

state contract law controls, and then

1:17:33

you've had case after case making

1:17:36

a dividing line between protecting the

1:17:38

banking power at issue, these federally

1:17:40

authorized confers powers, and

1:17:43

on the one hand, and state law where

1:17:45

it can creep in when you're talking about

1:17:47

the interaction and transactions with consumers. But

1:17:50

aren't the National Bank

1:17:52

interacting with consumers pursuant to

1:17:54

their power? So why don't

1:17:57

those two categories collapse? You

1:18:00

said they didn't. You said there's no federal

1:18:03

common law of contracts. There's no federal law

1:18:05

of torts. States in the

1:18:07

court said in their daily lives banks

1:18:09

can be regulated more by states than

1:18:12

the federal law because the states have

1:18:14

to supply state contract law, tort law.

1:18:17

All right. Well, speaking of what we said, you mentioned the

1:18:19

Anderson case. I read that case to be

1:18:21

about whether or not state

1:18:25

laws, quote, impose an undue burden

1:18:27

on the performance of the bank's

1:18:29

functions. So, I mean, yes,

1:18:31

you picked out some language that suggests that

1:18:33

this is about sort of

1:18:35

power at some level of generality, but

1:18:37

it seemed to me that this was

1:18:40

about whether the law issue in

1:18:42

that case was, quote, so burdensome,

1:18:44

end quote, as to be

1:18:46

inapplicable. It wasn't about the nature. It was

1:18:48

about, as people have said, the degree. I

1:18:50

think you're absolutely correct. And Anderson, and when

1:18:52

it contrasts the California case, is talking about

1:18:54

an undue burden because it didn't affect the

1:18:57

power and what the court said, and that's

1:18:59

why we have two tests. We have a

1:19:01

fallback test. One is if

1:19:03

it affects the national banking power and

1:19:05

controls the attribute of the product, preempted,

1:19:07

preempted, preempted. There is a second undue

1:19:10

burden test that looks at the practical

1:19:12

impact, but the delta between the two

1:19:14

sides is we think that can be

1:19:16

as a matter of law and looks

1:19:18

at a patchwork across 50 states.

1:19:21

The California case said it was preempted

1:19:23

without any factual record. In

1:19:25

Anderson, it said it wasn't

1:19:28

preempted with any factual record. They say with

1:19:30

no case, not one case, in 150 years

1:19:32

of precedent where this court looked to a

1:19:35

factual record. They're relying on some trial court

1:19:37

record. That's their best case when

1:19:39

the Supreme Court didn't even talk about it. I

1:19:41

think that pretty much tells you all you need

1:19:43

to know whether Congress intended a factual

1:19:46

record for banking preemption. Now, on

1:19:48

the OCC, I think there are three

1:19:50

reasons why it is just

1:19:52

simply implausible that by codifying Barnett Bank,

1:19:55

Congress tended to overrule it or somehow upset

1:19:57

it. The first is that what

1:19:59

I already said. You mentioned the 30 words of text that

1:20:02

says you need to follow Barnett Bank. The

1:20:04

second is there is a specific

1:20:06

provision in 25 BC, we rely

1:20:08

on it, the OCC relies on

1:20:10

it, that says OCC must follow

1:20:12

the legal standard of Barnett Bank

1:20:15

without any reference to the prevents

1:20:17

or significantly interferes. They

1:20:19

can't possibly mean two separate things. Congress

1:20:21

told OCC to follow Barnett Bank, not

1:20:23

to look at significant effect. The

1:20:26

third reason we think it's just completely doubly

1:20:28

bizarre and backwards that you would take Congress

1:20:30

being mad at the OCC and

1:20:33

imposing procedural requirements is somehow they

1:20:35

intended to impose a new

1:20:37

substantive standard on courts. When they weren't mad

1:20:39

at you, they weren't mad at courts and

1:20:41

impose a standard that no one's ever heard

1:20:43

of or applied before that you would go

1:20:45

fact by fact, fact by fact, law by

1:20:47

law, bank by bank. He

1:20:49

did a little fancy footwork when you said would this proceed bank

1:20:52

by bank. He answered by saying well that would be the OCC.

1:20:55

He never told you what would happen with

1:20:57

Justice Alito's question about what would happen if

1:20:59

Bank of America couldn't prove it,

1:21:01

but another national bank, Citibank,

1:21:03

could do it. There's

1:21:06

no answer to that. In terms of

1:21:08

the impact, the notion

1:21:10

that Mr.

1:21:13

Stewart speaking on behalf of not of the OCC but

1:21:15

the Justice Department, that you just have to look

1:21:18

at the records of the bank. The

1:21:20

biggest problem with something like interest rates, which

1:21:22

makes this a very easy case, is

1:21:24

today 2% is four times

1:21:27

the national savings. At the time of

1:21:29

Mr. Contaros, it was 33% times the

1:21:31

national savings rate. Excuse me,

1:21:33

that's Mr. Himes. At the time

1:21:35

of Mr. Contaros, it's 10 times. I

1:21:38

don't know what you think. Maybe

1:21:40

you should let the courts know. Let's look at ATM fees.

1:21:43

Four dollars sounds, I don't know, maybe $1.50. Then

1:21:46

we can go to credit card reward programs. We'd have

1:21:48

to have a consumer survey. I think I'd like 2%

1:21:51

back on my credit card, but maybe states say it

1:21:53

has to be 4%. I

1:21:56

just don't even know how they would do

1:21:58

this in terms of what the impact is. Banks

1:22:01

are in the business of money, so the

1:22:03

impact is not just the potential

1:22:06

for confusion and duplication and inconsistency and

1:22:08

the sheer 50 state regulators that you

1:22:10

would have to contend with and the

1:22:13

laws are constantly changing, but most things

1:22:15

with banks, if you take it out of one hand, it

1:22:18

comes out another. When

1:22:20

Congress studied this in 1973, they said- I'm

1:22:22

just glad I thought all the national banks were

1:22:24

pretty much the same in terms of their

1:22:28

powers. But we were talking about what

1:22:30

a state law is doing to the

1:22:32

national bank power, so it's not at

1:22:35

the level of a particular bank. And

1:22:38

any of the banks could make the argument,

1:22:40

and once they do, it would come up

1:22:42

to the Supreme Court and we would decide

1:22:44

ultimately, right? Well, that's this case. The Second

1:22:46

Circuit said a mortgage escrow account is a

1:22:49

direct assault on national bank powers. I

1:22:51

guess I just don't understand why it's so hard. I don't think it is hard. No, no, no.

1:22:54

What I'm saying is you're making the argument that it is

1:22:56

really going to be very challenging for

1:22:58

banks if we rule against

1:23:00

you in this case, and I don't understand why

1:23:03

that's the case. Well, you have since

1:23:05

the Reagan administration, a former OCC controller

1:23:07

telling you it would create seismic sea

1:23:09

change and uncertainty. So that's the view

1:23:11

of controllers from Reagan to all the

1:23:13

way with Biden officials. You haven't even

1:23:15

heard from the OCC, which regulates the

1:23:17

national banking system. That alone should scare

1:23:19

you tremendously, that you don't even have

1:23:21

the OCC up here. In terms of

1:23:24

how hard it would be, I don't

1:23:26

think I've heard a satisfactory answer on

1:23:28

what interest rate would be too much

1:23:30

and how national banks could make that

1:23:32

showing. But take just interest rates on

1:23:34

savings accounts. I don't even

1:23:36

know what the banks would say. They would say, well, we

1:23:38

can do it. We'll have to... No,

1:23:40

you have to say something is your burden. You

1:23:43

have the burden in the law to show this substantially interferes.

1:23:46

If your answer is, I don't know

1:23:48

what we would show, then I guess

1:23:50

you lose. What if 150

1:23:52

years of case law is relevant and Barnett Bank

1:23:54

codified it? Because in no case

1:23:56

has a bank, the Supreme Court ever say,

1:23:59

well, where's your... Franklin

1:24:01

itself is the best case on point. And

1:24:03

both, and I also think it's significant that the

1:24:06

court in Waters, that's the Supreme Court.

1:24:08

I mean, that's actually you.

1:24:10

You read Barnett Bank and had

1:24:12

the most sweeping language you could

1:24:14

possibly have about what Barnett Bank

1:24:16

meant. And it said states cannot

1:24:18

control banks, period. That's

1:24:20

the Supreme Court at that

1:24:22

interpretive Barnett Bank. So, you

1:24:25

know, and that's why I think OTC has always

1:24:27

taken this position. I'm going to give you

1:24:29

my full context because I looked at it.

1:24:32

It says the states can exercise

1:24:34

no control over national banks nor

1:24:37

in any way affect their operation,

1:24:40

except insofar as Congress

1:24:42

may see proper to permit. For

1:24:44

sure. And that's what the whole

1:24:46

issue is, how far do Congress permit here?

1:24:49

Well, two Solicitor Generals said in brief

1:24:51

before you what I said. So

1:24:53

I'm happy standing on OSG's view and

1:24:55

across several administrations about what Barnett Bank

1:24:58

means. I'm fine with

1:25:00

that. The state statutes have to

1:25:02

be non-discriminatory. Correct. So,

1:25:05

you know, one way you could look at this is if

1:25:07

a state statute is non-discriminatory, how

1:25:09

much damage could it really be

1:25:11

doing? And I think that's

1:25:13

part of the problem, which is what the Franklin

1:25:16

case illustrates and what this case illustrates is the

1:25:18

plaintiffs will always say, well, you applied it to

1:25:20

your state banks, so what's the problem? That's

1:25:23

the question. The problem... I mean, it seems as

1:25:25

though there should be a kind of presumption that

1:25:27

if the state is doing it for the state

1:25:29

banks, it's not really interfering

1:25:31

with bank powers in a way that

1:25:33

we should care about. There might be

1:25:35

exceptions to that, and that's what the

1:25:39

language is designed to accomplish.

1:25:42

You know, to pick the exceptions to

1:25:44

that where something has gone kerflui, such

1:25:46

that even a non-discriminatory

1:25:48

law does something special to

1:25:50

national banks. So two responses.

1:25:53

I think Franklin would have come out the other way, because

1:25:56

there was the New York Court

1:25:58

of Appeals said... there's

1:26:00

not a sufficient showing. But more importantly, and this

1:26:03

I think goes to the congressional design of the

1:26:05

National Bank Act, is that they're supposed to be,

1:26:07

you know, why have your name Bank of America

1:26:09

if you look like Bank of Ocean City or

1:26:11

Bank of Hawaii? You're supposed to be able to

1:26:13

walk into Bank of America and get one product

1:26:16

and not have 50 products and 50 states

1:26:18

and every time a state says change your

1:26:21

escrow, you have to change another aspect alone

1:26:23

on the origination. I totally get that

1:26:25

impulse that national banks don't want to

1:26:27

have to deal with patchwork, state

1:26:30

laws. But the presumption,

1:26:32

the baseline, that Congress said is

1:26:34

it's not preempted unless

1:26:37

discrimination or you can

1:26:39

prove significant impact. So

1:26:43

we can't take that argument very seriously

1:26:45

that it's just too much of an

1:26:47

impairment on national banks. They

1:26:49

have to deal with reality that we live in

1:26:51

a federal system with 50 states. Yeah,

1:26:53

I mean, it just seems like you're kind of reading the

1:26:55

provision. I mean, upside down you could read Barnett Bank the

1:26:57

same way and say this is... You could say upside down,

1:27:00

but that's what the statute said. You could

1:27:02

say 150 years of case law says states

1:27:04

can regulate unless there's a... Unless what Congress

1:27:07

said, right? I agree. And

1:27:09

I think that the court said it's preempted

1:27:11

under Barnett Bank if it prevents or significantly

1:27:13

interferes. And then you go to Barnett Bank

1:27:15

and it tells you, I think five times

1:27:18

that we read it in light of Franklin.

1:27:20

You mentioned earlier that you thought state

1:27:23

lending laws with respect to

1:27:25

race, religion and others are not preempted. Why?

1:27:29

So the case... On your view,

1:27:31

if states don't get a role

1:27:33

and you really Barnett Bank should

1:27:35

be inverting statute and the presumption

1:27:37

is national banks operate free of

1:27:39

state control, that

1:27:42

would seem to soon those laws too. Yeah. So

1:27:45

no for this fundamental reason and that

1:27:47

is that states have... I'm

1:27:49

sorry, national banks have no power whatsoever

1:27:52

to discriminate on the basis of race

1:27:54

or to commit fraud. And this court

1:27:56

in the 1924 case at First National

1:27:58

Bank versus Missouri... said, when

1:28:00

it said that state law that bans

1:28:03

national banks from having bank branches,

1:28:06

the court said it can't preempt it

1:28:08

because there's no either, no express

1:28:11

power or even implied power to do branches.

1:28:13

So I think the OCC has correctly taken

1:28:15

the view since 2004 that there is no,

1:28:17

there's simply

1:28:20

no power to do branches. So if I understand- Go,

1:28:22

please. If I understand your test

1:28:25

correctly, you're looking to see whether

1:28:27

a state is conditioning the exercise

1:28:30

of a national bank power. And

1:28:32

for sure, that's what fair lending laws

1:28:34

do. It says, you

1:28:37

can't make the loan decisions that

1:28:39

you want to make except conditional

1:28:42

on your satisfying sub-state law.

1:28:46

A lot of state laws can be explained

1:28:48

in just that way. And that's, I think

1:28:50

that that's the test you use in your brief. Yeah,

1:28:53

but- Fair lending laws are a condition on

1:28:55

a national bank's power. So is a law

1:28:57

that says you can't lend a mortgage to

1:28:59

a two-year-old. That's conditioning the bank's power on

1:29:03

making sure the person is 18. But

1:29:05

those laws aren't preempted. And I think the useful

1:29:07

dividing line is, are you changing the

1:29:09

attributes of the product of service? Absolutely

1:29:12

you are. You're saying

1:29:14

you have to lend to people you don't want

1:29:16

to lend to. But that's the same

1:29:18

way with a four-year-old. But if I could just get-

1:29:20

A four-year-old, a 24-year-old, whatever. And

1:29:23

just a second, counsel. You're going to be

1:29:25

a patchwork of states and the different judgments.

1:29:28

And you're going to disagree with some of them. And

1:29:31

all of them have to do with the core

1:29:33

banking powers of who you may lend to, who

1:29:35

you may open an account for, what interest you can

1:29:37

charge, and all of that. And

1:29:40

it seems to me, not to

1:29:42

put too fine a point on it, there's a bit

1:29:44

of wanting your cake and eating it too here. No,

1:29:47

because we're happy with, again, your precedent. Your

1:29:49

precedent has been very careful to make sure

1:29:51

that states can go right up to the

1:29:53

line. And I think Anderson says that. You

1:29:55

can talk about, you know, you

1:29:57

can interact with the account holder.

1:30:00

the bank and things like contract law, age

1:30:02

requirement, statute of frauds. And if I can

1:30:04

get back to discriminatory lending, banks don't have

1:30:06

any power to discriminate on the basis of

1:30:08

race, gender, sex, sexual orientation, but they sure

1:30:11

have to discriminate on the basis of income

1:30:13

status. So yes, if the state law said

1:30:15

you can't discriminate on the basis of income,

1:30:17

that's going to preempt it because there's a

1:30:19

federal duty to mitigating at risk. But

1:30:23

this is, again, and the same way with

1:30:25

fraud. I don't think fair lending

1:30:28

laws, state lending laws to prohibit fraud and

1:30:30

lending are preempted either. They just

1:30:32

have never been. You can discriminate on the basis of income

1:30:34

but not race. How about

1:30:36

redlining neighborhoods and things like that?

1:30:39

Disparate impact is, I mean, that's extremely heavily

1:30:41

regulated by federal law. But I'm

1:30:43

asking about non-discriminatory state laws,

1:30:45

then what? I

1:30:47

don't think any states have argued, sorry,

1:30:49

federal, national banks have argued disparate impact

1:30:51

laws are preempted because they are so- But

1:30:54

under your test, why wouldn't they? Well,

1:30:57

I mean, we can talk about the theory

1:31:00

behind disparate impact probably, but I think it's

1:31:02

one of those areas on how you consider,

1:31:04

how you look at disparate impact. You might

1:31:06

argue those are

1:31:08

preempted under your test. I don't

1:31:10

think so, but even if they did, it's

1:31:12

still the line that we're drawing is the

1:31:14

line this court has drawn, I think,

1:31:17

since Anderson. And

1:31:19

before that, that if you're not changing

1:31:22

the attribute, and I don't think it

1:31:24

changes the loan attribute to say, is

1:31:27

the person black or white or green, it's still

1:31:29

a loan with the same interest rate, the same

1:31:31

term. If you say state law says, I don't

1:31:33

want national banks paying less than 2% or

1:31:35

3% or 4% on savings accounts

1:31:38

or no mortgage loans that are under

1:31:41

29 months and 10 months, it's just

1:31:43

the product. That is literally the product. And I

1:31:45

think we talked about the credit cards and the

1:31:48

ATM fees, how much cash you can withdraw.

1:31:51

How much cash you can withdraw has nothing to

1:31:53

do with the consumer walking in. It literally is

1:31:55

the core banking service itself. And

1:31:57

this has been the workable standard. This has been

1:31:59

the settled expectations. and whether or not you have

1:32:01

to pay interest on the escrow account does or

1:32:03

does not have something to do with the consumer

1:32:06

walking in? Nothing. It's the nature

1:32:08

of the product. It's the interest rate on the loan.

1:32:10

It's no different than there's plenty of state laws that

1:32:12

control, you know, things like the term of the loan,

1:32:15

what's the maximum amount you can take out

1:32:17

on a mortgage loan. Those are all preempted,

1:32:20

yet states regulate that for state banks. This has

1:32:22

been, I mean, again, we've talked about the OCC.

1:32:26

This has been the law since 1983

1:32:28

for all real estate, but for things

1:32:30

like escrow, the escrow regulation came in

1:32:32

in 2004. So

1:32:34

national banks but for the Ninth Circuit, which

1:32:36

I think covers two state escrow laws, national

1:32:38

banks don't comply with state escrow laws unless they want

1:32:40

to because it's one

1:32:42

of the features they want to do to attract consumers.

1:32:45

In terms of how much money, I mean, these are very small dollar

1:32:47

amounts. Bank of America

1:32:49

put in its brief and it had evidence in the LOSNAC. I

1:32:51

think it's the LOSNAC I pronounced it. It

1:32:54

doesn't earn interest on these accounts and it costs

1:32:56

a lot of money to maintain them. So I

1:32:58

don't think it's so much that it's, again,

1:33:01

I don't know what the factual showing would

1:33:03

be, but I do know the other side

1:33:05

would just say New York banks comply with

1:33:07

it. So it's never going to be preempted. I'm

1:33:10

just trying to understand the sense of this distinction

1:33:12

you're making. And I didn't realize that you were

1:33:14

making this distinction. So I'm making this up on

1:33:16

the fly. But suppose there

1:33:18

were a state that said something like before

1:33:22

a loan can be denied, a person

1:33:24

has a right to see the bank president.

1:33:28

And that's very, it's actually

1:33:30

really super inconvenient

1:33:33

for the bank. That

1:33:35

would fall on your yes, a state can do that side

1:33:37

of the line. I think it

1:33:39

would probably fall on the no that the state can't.

1:33:41

It depends on how broad you interpret the sort of

1:33:43

the services associated with it. I

1:33:46

will say that there are state laws that regulate how the

1:33:48

banking statement has to look, what kind of receipts you have

1:33:50

to have. If you knew

1:33:52

the amount of federal regulations that are just so

1:33:55

exhaustive on this, that if banks had to comply

1:33:57

with 50 different kinds of patchwork of any

1:33:59

kind of debt, every law on that, but

1:34:01

sort of seeing who the bank, meeting

1:34:03

the bank president seems to be similar

1:34:05

on, you know, how the bank, how

1:34:07

the banking statement has to look. Yeah,

1:34:09

it's just suggestive of the

1:34:11

idea that it's hard to make

1:34:13

this distinction between what concerns your transaction with

1:34:16

a customer and what concerns your banking product,

1:34:18

which is what I thought you were saying.

1:34:20

I think it's very easy when you have

1:34:22

an interest rate. I think a harder one

1:34:25

is like the Anderson versus California. Well, so

1:34:27

it works for this case, but you're

1:34:29

asking us to do something that applies to

1:34:31

every kind of case. But it works for

1:34:33

every case that's been addressed by OCC's regulations

1:34:35

since the 2000s. I

1:34:38

mean, this is not, OCC goes through a

1:34:40

laundry list of preempted types of preempted. They

1:34:42

all go to the banking product. They

1:34:45

go to the mortgage loan. Well, the government

1:34:47

has disallowed that regulation and

1:34:49

said it's inconsistent with the statute. So I don't

1:34:51

know how much traction that gets you. I think

1:34:53

you just heard, you might as well have heard

1:34:55

from the Forest Service. I mean, they literally went

1:34:57

against the- I think we heard from the Solicitor

1:34:59

General of the United States on behalf of the

1:35:01

federal government. Contracting two other Solicitor Generals

1:35:04

and saying they didn't even consult with OCC. With all due

1:35:06

respect, this is a- Where is this

1:35:08

line that you've been talking about in your brief?

1:35:10

Can you direct me to it? I think the

1:35:12

line is- I didn't see it. I

1:35:15

think that's fair on the product. We may have only

1:35:18

mentioned the product thing once. The

1:35:20

main test is the control test at the Second Circuit

1:35:22

applied. Yeah, it's totally different than the control

1:35:24

test, isn't it? That's what

1:35:26

you're asking us to adopt. And wouldn't it, this

1:35:29

product versus consumer test

1:35:32

itself generate a lot of litigation

1:35:34

over border cases? I don't

1:35:36

think that when we tried to talk about

1:35:38

the difference with the definition of state consumer

1:35:41

financial law, we talked about- this is where

1:35:43

it gets very close. We talked about there's

1:35:45

a difference between controlling the banking power and

1:35:47

controlling the financial transaction with the consumer. And

1:35:49

I just think the explanation to that just

1:35:52

looks to the product. It's not in your brief. And

1:35:55

if I think it's different from the lower court opinion, what

1:35:57

are we supposed to do? And then you stick with our brief.

1:36:01

It's not in your brief. Stick

1:36:03

with our brief. Don't, don't, you didn't hear anything I

1:36:05

said. Well your brief, the first time

1:36:08

I've heard that. I

1:36:12

mean the problem is that your brief doesn't explain

1:36:14

fair lending laws. And in a

1:36:16

way what you're trying to do is

1:36:18

to gerrymander a world in which fair

1:36:20

lending laws, which everybody thinks kind of

1:36:22

have to apply to national banks, apply

1:36:25

to national banks, but nothing else does.

1:36:27

Yeah, and I don't think it's gerrymandering unless

1:36:29

you think the OCC has gerrymandered. I mean

1:36:31

you've had to have a workable rule since

1:36:33

states have had, excuse me, since national banks

1:36:35

have had real estate lending power since 1983.

1:36:39

And this has been the workable rule. The

1:36:41

OCC has carded off the loan. But

1:36:45

it is said at the same time, and it wrote to

1:36:47

Barney Frank in 2004, but we're going to put

1:36:49

fair lending laws to the side. Now there might

1:36:51

be some fair lending laws that might be problematic

1:36:54

when they run up to the duty to mitigate

1:36:56

risk. But generally banks just

1:36:58

don't have the power to discriminate or

1:37:00

commit fraud. And if

1:37:02

you can't ever answer a question at

1:37:04

oral argument in the brief, then I'm not sure why we

1:37:06

have an oral argument. It's pretty

1:37:08

central. It's

1:37:11

not an incidental question. It's

1:37:13

what's preempted. And your

1:37:16

brief says everything's preempted, controlled. I

1:37:18

think so. And now you're saying,

1:37:20

there's this new distinction that we've

1:37:23

somehow distilled from our cases that

1:37:25

heretofore nobody has mentioned. So the

1:37:27

amount of non-preempted laws is the exact same

1:37:29

in the brief. The fair lending and all

1:37:31

generally applicable laws that go to how you

1:37:34

form contracts. The only one I add, and Anderson,

1:37:37

the only one I added is the fraud laws.

1:37:39

I don't think those are in the briefs, but

1:37:41

I think they follow. So if you don't want

1:37:43

to consider the fraud laws, that's fine. But the

1:37:46

basic distinction dividing line, we spent

1:37:48

pages and pages saying this court has recognized

1:37:50

all the laws that aren't preempted, starting with

1:37:52

state contract laws. Thank

1:37:56

you, counsel, Justice Thomas. Justice Alito. Well,

1:38:00

I share the

1:38:03

difficulty that's been expressed in

1:38:05

understanding the difference between a state

1:38:08

law that affects a

1:38:11

national bank's exercise of the banking

1:38:13

power and a state law that

1:38:15

regulates the way

1:38:17

in which the bank exercises

1:38:22

that power in dealing

1:38:25

with its customers. Is

1:38:28

there some other way to express

1:38:30

this? Is

1:38:32

there something else if we look at the

1:38:35

instances that have been held to fall

1:38:37

on the latter side of that line,

1:38:40

some other characteristic that could be identified

1:38:42

that would explain the difference? Well, the

1:38:44

reason why I like what I'm giving

1:38:46

you is because it's the statute defined

1:38:49

state consumer financial laws in terms of

1:38:51

the transaction. So we stuck

1:38:53

to the text of financial transaction and

1:38:55

we think Barnett Bank is talking about

1:38:57

the national banking power, but because there

1:38:59

is this sort of semantic

1:39:02

issue, well, regulate is

1:39:04

regulated, you're regulating the power, you're regulating

1:39:06

the transaction, it helps to explain

1:39:08

what that means. If you wanted the case, it

1:39:10

would be Anderson. Anderson talks

1:39:12

about it is just changing

1:39:15

the identity of the, it's no

1:39:17

different than if you had like a

1:39:19

garnishment or missing person, but it doesn't

1:39:21

affect the underlying function or powers of

1:39:23

the bank. And this is

1:39:26

a loan. This is literally like the most important

1:39:28

thing they do other than to take deposits. But

1:39:31

we are, there is the problem that,

1:39:34

and you've provided an answer, I'll

1:39:37

have to think about it, as

1:39:39

to why your interpretation

1:39:41

doesn't preempt everything, but there's

1:39:44

the problem on the other side

1:39:46

that Mr. Taylor's argument seems to

1:39:48

preempt nothing. If

1:39:52

you can presume that anything

1:39:55

that's good, that's okay for a state

1:39:57

bank is also okay for a national

1:39:59

bank, then the definition nothing is going

1:40:01

to be preempted. Maybe

1:40:03

he'll have an explanation on rebuttal

1:40:07

about what

1:40:09

his interpretation is.

1:40:11

Right, and the reason I like my position

1:40:13

better is because I think I've got the status quo on

1:40:15

my side. What they have is that

1:40:17

Congress is really angry at OCC, but

1:40:20

there's no suggestion in the legislative history or

1:40:23

anything else that they wanted to

1:40:25

create all this massive stability. This is the time of

1:40:27

the Great Recession. The notion

1:40:29

that they wanted to impose on every national

1:40:31

bank some query of we no longer know

1:40:33

whether the laws of 50 states apply to

1:40:36

every single thing we do without anyone noticing.

1:40:39

It just seems to me that this is what

1:40:42

the former controller brief said it would be a

1:40:44

sea change. Okay, one

1:40:46

final question just for clarity. Could you

1:40:48

walk through the text and show why

1:40:50

your interpretation is consistent with

1:40:52

the text, the relevant text?

1:40:55

Yes, so the 30 words of text

1:40:57

about Barnett Bank, who want to talk

1:40:59

about significantly interfere. I

1:41:01

think the word significant does some work because

1:41:03

it does a significant amount of work because

1:41:05

not any law that could be said to

1:41:07

interfere with the banking power. We've talked about

1:41:09

the fair lending laws, talked about the age

1:41:12

requirements, the writing requirements. It has

1:41:14

to be significant that it has to go to the

1:41:16

authorized federal power. Is

1:41:19

the thing that's codified the

1:41:22

words taken from Barnett Bank

1:41:24

significantly interferes etcetera or is it the

1:41:26

holding of Barnett Bank? Is it how

1:41:30

Barnett Bank itself understood those

1:41:32

words? The latter. I think

1:41:34

you could say it's both but it's clearly

1:41:36

the latter. I think in their view you

1:41:38

didn't have to enact any reference to Barnett

1:41:40

Bank because they just start with significant interference.

1:41:43

Case by case? Case by

1:41:45

case refers to the OCC in terms of

1:41:47

they're saying if you're going to proceed by

1:41:49

order or regulation you'd have to just look

1:41:51

at escrow laws because it has to be

1:41:53

a substantial, I mean you might have a

1:41:55

debate about what's the substantial equivalent of escrow

1:41:58

laws but case by case is not... referring

1:42:00

to facts, it's referring to you can't just

1:42:02

say we want to preempt everything on mortgage

1:42:04

loans. You have to look at like, you

1:42:06

know, escrow, down payment, maximum, you have to

1:42:09

just go kind of law by law. But

1:42:11

it's talking about the OTC. Thank

1:42:13

you. Does this so to me or? Just

1:42:17

King, Justice Gorsuch, Justice

1:42:21

Barrett. I just

1:42:23

have one thing on your distinction because I'm

1:42:25

still trying to follow it.

1:42:28

You rely on Anderson. And

1:42:32

I guess the other case that sort

1:42:34

of implicates the same facts is Anderson

1:42:36

is the California case, which you talked

1:42:39

about. And the problem I'm

1:42:41

having with your distinction between

1:42:43

product or power and

1:42:46

the transaction is that in

1:42:49

California, the

1:42:51

court describes the

1:42:53

law at issue there, which it says

1:42:56

is preempted as a

1:42:58

statute that attempts to qualify

1:43:01

in an unusual way agreements between

1:43:03

national banks and their customers and

1:43:06

may cause them to hesitate to

1:43:08

subject their funds to possible confiscation.

1:43:11

So it seems as though the court in this

1:43:13

case says the reason why you're

1:43:15

preempted is because you

1:43:17

are trying this law is trying

1:43:20

to regulate the transaction between

1:43:22

the bank, which you say is the reason why

1:43:24

in Anderson they would say it's not preempted. So

1:43:26

I don't 100 percent.

1:43:28

And you're just completely correct. What we're

1:43:30

saying is you have the control on

1:43:33

the power of the baking product. And there's

1:43:35

a second fallback test, which is the undue

1:43:37

burden. And that undue burden

1:43:39

is the practical impact. So if you

1:43:42

had a state law that said that

1:43:44

is the difference between California and the

1:43:46

Kentucky law that said the

1:43:49

minimum age requirement is 61 to open up

1:43:51

a mortgage. Well, that

1:43:53

is a law of

1:43:55

majority. It clearly would oppose

1:43:58

an unusual relationship on the relationship between

1:44:00

the state and the state. between the

1:44:02

bank and its customers. So we do

1:44:04

think you could go and preempt these

1:44:06

laws that do interact with the consumer

1:44:08

and the state. Another one

1:44:10

would be a state, national banks or any bank

1:44:12

can only be open for one hour during the

1:44:14

week. That's going to be preempted. Or you

1:44:16

have to pay tellers $1,000 an hour. It's

1:44:19

going to be preempted even though, of course,

1:44:21

Title VII applies to national banks. But I

1:44:23

do think the California case leaves open and

1:44:25

Anderson says if the state law is so

1:44:27

unusual with respect to the bank and its

1:44:30

consumers to the point that it's interfering with their

1:44:32

operations, it will be preempted. Thank you. Thank

1:44:35

you, counsel. Rebuttal, Mr. Taylor. Thank you, Mr. Chief Justice.

1:44:40

Just a few quick points

1:44:42

in rebuttal. My friend

1:44:44

says that the statute contains two

1:44:46

different tests. One for when states

1:44:49

dictate the attributes of the product

1:44:51

or service, which I think she

1:44:53

said is preempted, preempted, preempted. And

1:44:55

the second, undue burden test for some

1:44:57

other category of laws. Now

1:45:00

that test is made up, atextual and

1:45:02

yes, Justice Gorsuch appears for the first

1:45:04

time at argument. And this court

1:45:07

in Cuomo, I'll just note, rejected

1:45:09

a similarly atextual test, although it's not

1:45:11

exactly the same, as inconsistent with the

1:45:13

text of the statute. And the same

1:45:15

is true here. Now they read

1:45:18

30 words of the text of the

1:45:20

statute, which they say is a love

1:45:22

letter to Barnett Bank, as excising the

1:45:24

very standard that is codified and is

1:45:26

nullifying seven pages of their statutory appendix,

1:45:29

which is the entire statute, so

1:45:32

that the statute would have no real

1:45:34

world effect. Now, Justice Sotomayor, you pointed

1:45:36

out that the statute here uses the

1:45:38

phrase only if, which is somewhat unusual

1:45:40

for a preemption provision and suggests that

1:45:42

in the real world it's as much

1:45:45

an anti-preemption clause as a preemption clause.

1:45:47

But it's not an exotic provision, Justice

1:45:49

Kagan. And if you look at page 15 of

1:45:51

our reply brief, this court has actually

1:45:54

adopted a significant impact test. That's the

1:45:56

word this court has used, even though

1:45:58

it's not in the text. of the

1:46:00

statute related to a cluster

1:46:03

of cases. And this Court made that up

1:46:05

as an administrable line. And if it's comfortable

1:46:07

with that as the line when it's not

1:46:09

in the statute, then it should be comfortable

1:46:11

with that as the line when it is

1:46:13

in the statute. Now, there was a cluster

1:46:15

of questions about the practical effect, and I

1:46:17

just would say three things. The first is

1:46:19

the importance of a non-discriminatory law. That's why

1:46:21

a lot of their laws are hypos and

1:46:23

not reality, Justice Kagan. But Justice Alito, that

1:46:25

doesn't mean that that is the entire test,

1:46:27

just like it would have been under the

1:46:29

Treasury Department. You still have laws that

1:46:31

conflict as in Barnett Bank, and you still have

1:46:33

laws that, where there's a real significant interference. Justice

1:46:35

Kagan, you gave a hypo where a bank couldn't

1:46:38

make a loan unless a person could talk to

1:46:40

the president of the bank. If that's non-discriminatory, it

1:46:42

sounds a lot like significant interference to me. And

1:46:45

the third point I would make is there's still a

1:46:47

role for the OCC to play here. It can do

1:46:49

the job that Congress had expected it to do if

1:46:53

there is a real problem, like my friend on

1:46:55

the other side claims. And their

1:46:57

position that this would so mayhem is

1:46:59

pretty offensive to federalism. The idea is

1:47:01

that nationwide companies might have to comply with

1:47:04

non-discriminatory state laws that don't conflict with the

1:47:06

text of a statute in the states where

1:47:08

they do business, and that they should be

1:47:10

entitled to preempt those statutes as

1:47:13

a matter of law without having to show

1:47:15

significant interference. And I think that's just inconsistent

1:47:17

with the way this typically approaches questions

1:47:21

under the Supremacy Clause. And finally,

1:47:23

I would note that it's quite

1:47:25

clear that Congress passed the statute to do

1:47:27

something. It was reacting against what the OCC

1:47:29

had done. The OCC said the same 2004

1:47:32

rule remains in effect and the same list

1:47:34

of laws are preempted. And Congress said, no,

1:47:36

we want the statute to have some real

1:47:38

effect. And my friend on the other side

1:47:40

reads the statute to have no real-world effect.

1:47:42

Thank you very much. Thank you, counsel. The

1:47:44

case is submitted.

Rate

Join Podchaser to...

  • Rate podcasts and episodes
  • Follow podcasts and creators
  • Create podcast and episode lists
  • & much more

Episode Tags

Do you host or manage this podcast?
Claim and edit this page to your liking.
,

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features